Thursday, November 20, 2014

Shifting Economic Regimes for Retail in the Philippines: External Impetus Amidst the Workings of Domestic Politics

This is an Author's Original Manuscript of an article published by Taylor & Francis Group in “The International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research” on 2014, available online: http://www.tandfonline.com/dx.doi.org/10.1080/09593969.2014.970211


Bing Baltazar C. Brillo[1]

Abstract

In the prevailing globalized world order, shifting economic regimes is principally understood via the overriding-external-impetus lens where international demand holds sway over domestic policy making. Considering the complexity of the process and the possibility of varying outcomes, the perspective evidently limits the function of domestic politics in changing regimes. In elucidating how the dynamics of domestic politics respond to external impetuses and play out in relation to regime shifts, this paper looks into the two cases of regime shifts in retail in the Philippines: Republic Act (RA) 1180, a protectionist regime enacted in 1954 and RA 8762, a liberalized regime legislated in 2000. The study examines the interface and convergence of three salient factors— external-internal impetus, presidential intervention and the changing dynamics in the retail sector— that were pivotal in both regime shifts. Specifically, the external-internal impetus helped set off the move for regime shift; the sitting President played a crucial role in the success of the legislation in Congress; and the retail sector exemplified varying dynamics (e.g. consolidation in RA 1180 and fragmentation in RA 8762) which facilitated the enactment of the laws. The study also underscores two key points: (1) while the initiative to adopt or change economic regimes for a government will continue to have external impetus, the success of regime shift as well as the substance of its specific policy will be essentially determined by the workings of domestic politics; and (2) the legislative experience characterizes the contemporary link between global influence and domestic dynamics in policy making. The paper closes with a note on the case study’s implications on retail globalization in Southeast Asia.

Keywords: retail, regime shift, domestic politics, Republic Act 1180 and Republic Act 8762

Introduction
           
In the contemporary globalized era, two things have characterized economic regime shifts in governments: one, it is a difficult and contentious process (see Howlett and Ramesh 1995, Reich 2002, Stein et al.2005, Bardach 2006 and Stewart 2008), and two, it is a top-down and externally driven process (see O’Brien 1992, Ohmae 1996, Greider 1997, Gray 1998 and Hay 2006). In terms of the first aspect, shifting regime is problematic, since it is inherently easier to continue an existing policy than to radically reform it or totally replace it. Since changing regime entails altering the status quo, naturally, those benefiting from the current setup would fight tooth and nail to defend and preserve their advantage. This impediment is exacerbated by the risks involved in changing regime, as there is no guarantee that shifting regime will not have detrimental effects or unintended consequences, and there is always the potential that vested interests will seize the occasion. Moreover, shifting regime may also suffer from collective action dilemma— when the costs of regulatory change are immediately felt by, and concentrated on, a specific group, while the perceived benefits are long-term and spread over a much larger group (Olsen 1965), or when the affected group is highly organized, affluent and well-connected, while the benefiting group is poorly organized, financially weak and less influential (Reich 2002)— which create strong incentives against regime shifts.

With respect to second aspect, regime shifts, under the neoliberal orthodoxy, are considered to be processes instigated mainly by external impetus. Specifically, the initiative to pursue policy change, particularly in trade and finance, is deemed to be “dictated” from the outside by global institutions (e.g. the World Trade Organization [WTO], Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation [APEC], the International Monetary Fund [IMF] and the World Bank [WB]). This external intervention is rationalized, in theory, as the norm in the globalized capitalist system (see Reich 1991, Ohmae 1996, Greider 1997 and Gray 1998), and usually enforced, in practice, through prescribed policy reforms and loan conditionalities (see Reed, 1992, Simon 1995, Wood 1997 and Bracking 1999). Under this setup, the international demand for shifting economic regimes is understood as undermining governments by holding sway over domestic policy making. This arrangement implies that the link between the external impetus and domestic politics is directionally skewed in favor of the former.

Considering its complexity, understanding regime shift plainly via the overriding-external-impetus lens is tantamount to oversimplification. This explanatory inadequacy is evident in accounting for the multitude of policy outcomes experienced by countries undergoing regime change— a universal standard policy imposed by global institutions when legislated by individual countries results in various forms. In rationalizing the variation of policies among countries, scholars have attributed it to factors such as the mixed effect of globalization vis-à-vis government capacity (see Held et al. 1999, Woods 2000, Garrett 2000, Dicken 2003 and Sorensen 2006), the consequence of existing institutional arrangements (see Cox and McCubbins 2001, Shugart and Haggard 2001, Tsebelis 2002 and Stein et al.2005), and the influence of the prevailing practice of politics (see Wade 1990, Tansey 1995, Weiss 1998 and Leftwich 2000). Combined, these factors points to one key variable— the dynamics of domestic politics. The importance of domestic politics has been underscored in the burgeoning literature on retail globalization, particularly in the concept of territorial embeddedness (see Wrigley et al. 2005, Coe and Lee 2006, Coe and Wrigley 2009; see also Dicken et al. 2001, Henderson et al. 2002 and Yeung 2005). The embedded concept explicitly recognizes the influence of socio-economic-political factors, such as the specificities of domestic dynamics (e.g. national markets) and the demands of institutional contexts, in transnational retail expansion (see Tokatli and Eldener 2002, Sang 2003, Wang 2003 and Tilly 2007). Thus, following the mentioned scholarly works, understanding the intricacies of regime shifts suggest the need for a proper reading of the workings of domestic politics; specifically, how it responds to external impetus and the way it plays out in the policy making process and determines outcomes.

Thus, to elucidate the intricacies of regime shift and the significance of the workings of domestic politics, this paper examines two cases of regime shifts in retail that occurred in the Philippines. The first is Republic Act (RA) 1180, a protectionist regime enacted in 1954 and the second is RA 8762, a liberalized regime legislated in 2000. Despite the two laws’ opposing ideological orientations, both regime shifts share similarities, such as being influenced by international economic trends, took long difficult paths to legislate, and involved powerful interests. In analyzing the specificities of domestic politics in the regime shifts, the interface of three key factors is underscored: external-internal impetus, presidential involvement, and the retail sector’s dynamics. These factors were emphasized since the literature suggests their centrality in Philippine legislative politics (e.g. for external-internal impetus [see Constantino 1970, Lichauco 1973, Bello and Rivera 1977], for presidential intervention [see Gutierrez 1994, Caoili 2006, Velasco 2006], and for the business sector’s influence [see De Dios 1990, Montes 1992, Hutchroft 1993, Hutchroft 1998, Almonte 2007]). The paper proceeds as follows: the first part presents a narrative of the policy making of RA 1180 and RA 8762, and the second part discusses the interface of the underlying factors in the two regime shifts. The paper concludes with a discussion of the implications of the Philippine experience by focusing on the link between external demand and domestic politics in contemporary policy making.

The Shifting Economic Regime in Retail: RA 1180

The move to change the regulatory regime in retail had a long gestation period. During the Spanish and the American colonization periods and up to the establishment of the Philippine republic in 1946, the country had a liberalized system in retail. Doing business in retail was open not only to Filipinos but also to resident foreigners. Since the 1600s, the retail sector in the country had been overwhelmingly dominated by aliens, particularly Chinese immigrant retailers. In 1948, the Bureau of the Census and Statistics reported that 98.5 percent of alien retailers in the country were Chinese. Also, the Chinese immigrant retailers owned 61 percent of the retail businesses, compared to Filipinos who only owned 32 percent (Agpalo 1962). This longtime Chinese dominance of the retail industry had become a sensitive issue among Filipinos, since they saw this as detrimental to them and to the country as a whole. Retail was, and indeed still is, considered a critical sector of the Philippine economy, as it provided massive employment, contributed significantly to the gross domestic product (GDP)[2] and linked the other sectors of the economy to the consumers. Hence, the common thinking among Filipinos was that it should not be left in the hands of aliens. In time, this perception became a stimulus for the demand to nationalize the retail sector in the country.

There were sporadic appeals to free the retail industry from the Chinese immigrants’ control from the early 1900s. The organized mobilization, however, only began during the closing stages of American colonization, when the country experienced the resurgence of nationalism. The nationalist sentiment was mainly associated with the global clamor for self-determination in nation building; a phenomenon widely accepted among many newly independent developing countries at the time. In particular, the external impetus for self-determination was propelled by the rise in the world stage of dependency theory and its preferred strategy— import substitution industrialization (ISI). Here, the common theme was that countries must break free from their dependence on first world countries and pursue autonomous national development strategies (see Prebisch 1950, Baran 1957, Nurkse 1961 and Frank 1967). In other words, the political independence gained must go hand in hand with economic independence. This notion became the popular slogan among the political leaders of the newly independent Philippine government (Constantino 1975, Agoncillo 1990). In the domestic economy, this thinking translated to economic protectionism. It became the norm for the government to enact policies that were designed to protect or give advantage to local industries (e.g. market or tax advantage). Protectionist policies were considered necessary to nurture domestic industries and businesses, especially against foreign competition. In retail, this protectionist agenda was expressed through a direct call for the government to emancipate the retail sector from alien control via nationalization.

Internally, protectionism in retail was also fueled by the economic prosperity experienced by the country. The Bureau of the Census and Statistics reported that the total trade of the Philippines more than doubled from 720.1 million pesos in 1946 to 1,695.9 million pesos in 1953. This affluence led to some Filipinos becoming wealthy,[3] and in turn, set off the thought among them of entering the lucrative retail sector (Agpalo 1962). Early on, the intent to break the alien stranglehold on retail was manifested in the launching of the Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines’ (CCP) First National Convention of Filipino Businessmen in 1929, and the founding of the National Economic Protectionism Association (NEPA) and the Association for the Nationalization of Retail Trade in 1934. These organizations directly called for the government to prohibit aliens from engaging in retail (Agpalo 1962). Their contention was that the Filipino retailers were financially and organizationally incapable of competing against the alien retailers; hence, the government must intervene to free the sector from alien domination (Congress of the Philippines 1954). With this intent, naturally, it resulted in resentment between the Filipino business community and the Chinese immigrant retailers.

The Filipino business community’s effort to nationalize retail, however, was perennially thwarted in the legislature. The retail nationalization bill had been regularly introduced in Congress from the Commonwealth period[4] to the granting of independence.[5] On all occasions, the bill did not materialize into law. This outcome was due principally to the strong lobby of the alien retailers, especially the Chinese immigrant retailers, in Congress. The alien retailers’ success was attributable to two factors: first, their inherent advantage, and second, the intrinsic weakness of the Filipino business organizations. In terms of the first advantage, the alien retailers had financial leverage and help from their respective governments. The alien retailers were a significant source of capital in the domestic economy and enjoyed strong external support, as the Taiwanese, the Japanese and the American governments exerted pressure on the Philippine government.

With respect to the second dimension, the Filipino business organizations were still in a nascent stage of development. The principal groups pushing the nationalization of retail were newly established (e.g. the Filipino Retail Merchants’ Association in 1948, the Filipino Economic Emancipation Organization in 1952, the United Filipino Retailers and Cooperative Association in 1952, and the Filipino Retail Business Movement in 1953) compared to the alien retailers’ organizations (e.g. the Chinese General Chamber of Commerce [CGCC][6] / the Federation of Chinese Chambers of Commerce [FCCC] and the American Chamber of Commerce [ACC]) which had been formed way before. By implication, the Filipino business organizations were still in the phase of building-consolidating relative to the alien retailers’ organizations which were already entrenched, cohesive and well-funded (Jison 1954, Reyes 1955). In this context, the emerging Filipino business community lacked the political weight needed to neutralize the influence of the alien retailers and their governments.

The influence over the Philippine government, particularly, in the executive and the legislative branches favored the alien retailers. The legislature was perennially the haven of wealthy Filipinos (Gutierrez 1994, Coronel et al. 2004, Caoili 2006). With this composition, naturally the First Congress and the Second Congress were sympathetic to the cause of the local business community, and thus, supported the Bill to nationalize retail. The executive, on the other hand, was accommodating to the lobby of the alien retailers and their home governments. The Presidents, one way or another, made crucial efforts to preclude the enactment of the nationalization bill in the legislature. For instance, President Manuel Quezon (Commonwealth Republic, 1935-1944) moved for the postponement of the filing of the Bill, President Sergio Osmen͂a (1944-1946) vetoed the Bill, President Manuel Roxas (1946-1948) did not support the move to nationalize retail, and President Elpido Quirino (1948-1953) did not extend the session of Congress to salvage the Bill (Agpalo 1962). Here, the rationale used for not supporting the nationalization bill was its repercussion on the economy. Specifically, it was argued that disenfranchising alien retailers might create a vacuum in the domestic market (which the Filipino retailers are incapable of filling in), and expose the country to retaliation from the governments of alien retailers (Congress of the Philippines 1954). Overall, this political equation was favorable to the alien retailers, since in the history of Philippine politics, the President is the crucial actor on key legislations, as Congress usually only takes cue from the former (Gutierrez 1994, Caoili 2006, Velasco 2006).

After the 1953 Congressional-Presidential election, the political equation was significantly altered. The elections resulted in a government under a single party. The Third Congress (i.e. the Senate and the House) and the executive branch were controlled by the Nationalista Party, whose political agenda was supportive of economic protectionism. Since the previous legislatures (i.e. the First Congress and the Second Congress) already supported the proposal to nationalize retail, the major change was the election of President Ramon Magsaysay (Agpalo 1962). President Magsaysay, unlike his predecessors, was open to the idea of nationalizing retail. This change in the political equation was complemented by the consolidation of the Filipino business community. Since the 1930s, the Filipino business organizations had been building up their efforts in pushing for the nationalization bill. With the strengthening of the Filipino business organizations, they were ready to offset the influence of the alien retailers, particularly, Chinese immigrant retailers, in government. With this development, President Magsaysay effectively moved in to nationalize retail by strongly endorsing its legislation in the executive-legislative conference and by certifying its urgency in Congress.

Under the context discussed, the Third Congress enacted RA 1180 in May 1954, officially nationalizing the retail sector in the Philippines. RA 1180 marked a regime shift in retail from an open to a closed system. The law effectively prohibited aliens from directly or indirectly engaging in retail in the country. Although regime shift implies radical policy change, ironically, RA 1180 was conservative in essence. This outcome was primarily due to the two crucial stipulations that were included in the law which, in effect, significantly diluted its regulatory nature. In particular:

(1)   That a person who is not a citizen of the Philippines, or an association, partnership, or corporation not wholly owned by citizens of the Philippines, which is actually engaged in the said business on May, fifteen, nineteen hundred and fifty-four, shall be entitled to continue to engage therein, unless its license is forfeited in accordance herewith, until his death or voluntary retirement from said business, in the case of a natural person, and for a period of ten years from the date of the approval of this Act or until the expiration of the term of the association or partnership or of the corporate existence of the corporation, whichever event comes first, in the case of juridical persons.

(2)   Nothing contained in this Act shall in any way impair or abridge whatever rights may be granted to citizens and juridical entities of the United States of America under the Executive Agreement signed on July fourth, nineteen hundred and forty-six, between that country and the Republic of the Philippines (see RA 1180, Section 1, paragraph 1 and 2).

The first stipulation was a concession made to directly appease the Chinese immigrant retailers. The stipulation gave the alien retailers the legitimate prospect of continuing their business upon the implementation of the law, and the time to apply for Filipino citizenship (Martinez-Santos 2000). The second stipulation was a concession made to American retailers operating in the country. The stipulation exempted them from the law, since it assured the continuity of the Bell Trade Act of 1946, which guaranteed parity rights to American citizens[7] (Schirmer and Shalom 1987, Agoncillo 1990). These concessions were a tactical maneuver taken in the legislation of RA 1180; as they were the only way for President Magsaysay and the Congress to mollify the protestation of the alien retailers, while coming up with a nationalizing law that catered to the plea of the Filipino business community. In other words, the enactment of the law manifested the influence of the Filipino business community and the conservativeness of the law revealed the enduring influence of alien retailers.

The Shifting Economic Regime in Retail: RA 8762

By the 1990s, the soundness of RA 1180 was being questioned. For one, the protectionist regime had resulted in an oligopoly, wherein the industry was controlled by few players, particularly Chinese-Filipino retailers (Philippines Special Report 2002). The top three local retailers had captured close to 40 percent of the total sales of the retail sector (Congress of the Philippines 1999). It was also contended that the regulation had outlived its purpose. The law was originally intended as a remedy against the Chinese immigrant retailers’ control of the retail industry. But with the mass naturalization— Chinese immigrants becoming Filipino citizens— ironically, RA 1180 became a shield for Chinese Filipino retailers against foreign competition and for preserving their monopoly of the industry. Furthermore, it was argued that the regulation did not translate into substantive growth for the retail industry after four decades of operation. The Philippine retail sector had only grown to 10.9 percent of the GDP compared to the approximately 18 percent average among Southeast Asian countries at that time (Patalinghug 1996). Taken as a whole, these interlocking contentions became a motivation for the domestic demand to repeal RA 1180.

The idea to amend RA 1180 gradually developed in government after the People Power Revolution in 1986. The notion was instigated when the newly-installed administration of President Corazon Aquino officially adopted liberalization as the government’s economic strategy in dealing with the stagnant economy. This decision was to keep up with the global trend in economic thinking among many developing countries in the 1980s. It was also an action aligning the Philippines with the neoliberal bandwagon that was popular among the members of the ASEAN community. The external impetus was propelled by the primacy in the world stage of neoliberal economic theory, which gave high regard to market and trade oriented policies. Here, the core principles of deregulation, privatization, foreign investment and open trade became the guiding tenets of governments in economic development (see Balassa 1981, Lal 1983, Hayek 1990 and Toye 1993). Following this, the C. Aquino government started its liberalization agenda with the legislation of RA 7042— the Foreign Investment Act— in 1991, and with the agreement of establishing the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) in 1992.The former was considered as the precursor law that would pave the way for the legislation of other liberalization policies, and the latter was regarded as commitment by the government to open the domestic economy by 2008 through removal of trade restrictions. These governmental actions were ‘in sync’ with the plan to open key sectors of the domestic economy, which included the liberalization of retail (i.e. opening the sector to foreigner retailers).

In pushing for a broad economic liberalization agenda, however, President C. Aquino had limited success. The mediocre performance was attributable to being a transitional government. Her administration had succeeded the 20-year Marcos regime via extra-constitutional means, inherited a bankrupt and debt-ridden economy, and was hounded by a series of coup attempts (De Dios and Hutchcroft 2003). The political-economic instability caused the C. Aquino government to embrace a modest push in liberalizing the economy. It became prudent for the government not to further shake the status quo by pursuing highly divisive policies. Hence, as governmental stability became the priority, contentious policies, such as the move to amend RA 1180— the retail nationalization law—were put on the back burner, so to speak, since shifting regime in retail would pit the C. Aquino administration directly against the economically entrenched Filipino-Chinese retailers.

            When President Fidel Ramos was elected in 1992, his government did not only follow the economic liberalization program of his predecessor, but significantly accelerated it. The government liberalized key sectors of the economy, such as telecommunications, airlines, shipping, banking and insurance, and joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995 (De Dios and Hutchcroft 2003, Almonte 2007). In line with this, the government moved for the liberalization of retail in 1995 by formally pushing for the amendment of RA 1180 in Congress. The move, however, did not prosper, as the amended bill was repeatedly blocked in the legislature, specifically, in the Ninth Congress (1992-1995) and the Tenth Congress (1995-1998). The failure to pass the repealing law was mainly attributable to the strong opposition of the big retailers, particularly, the influential Chinese-Filipino retailers and the predilection of the legislature to favour business interests. In terms of the former, the big retailers expected to bear the brunt of the regime shift, since allowing the entry of foreign retailers would mean more competitors in the market, and hence, risk their dominance of the industry. With regards the latter, as the Philippine Congress is perennially the home of wealthy individuals and businessmen, naturally, the institution is more sensitive to business interest (Gutierrez 1994, Coronel et al. 2004, Caoili 2006).

The political equation changed when President Estrada got elected in 1998. President Estrada sustained the economic liberalization program of his predecessor, including the repeal of RA 1180. At the beginning of his term, President Estrada conveyed to Congress that his government would prioritize the push for the liberalization of retail. This intent was manifested when the administration’s economic managers were instructed to supply a working draft of the repealing bill and when President Estrada certified it as a priority in Congress. The step was significant. For one, unlike President Ramos, who had to contend with time constraint at the end of his term, President Estrada commenced his move early on in his term, which gave him ample time to succeed. Secondly, President Estrada, at this point, was still very popular and enjoyed widespread backing from the legislators. Under this context, support among the business community (except for the big retailers) to repeal RA 1180 gradually snowballed. In particular, the move was strongly supported by the umbrella associations of the business sector (i.e. the Philippine Chamber of Commerce and Industry and the Federation of Filipino-Chinese Chamber of Commerce and Industry) and the foreign business community in the country (i.e. American Chamber of Commerce, European Chamber of Commerce, and the Australian/New Zealand Chamber of Commerce). Furthermore, the Consumer Union of the Philippines, which is the umbrella organization of consumer groups, also joined the bandwagon and strongly supported the move of the administration. Here, the consumer groups saw that opening retail to foreign competition would be to their advantage, as it entailed more choices of goods for the consumers (Congress of the Philippines 1998).

The swelling of support for the repeal of RA 1180 was paralleled by the change of the dynamics in the retail sector. On one hand, the small retailers, particularly the operators of sari-sari stores (i.e. the small neighborhood convenience stores), which comprised 90 percent of the retail stores[8] openly supported the move for liberalizing retail. They rationalized that the increase in number of retailers (i.e. from the entry of foreign retailers) would mean more alternatives for them to source their supplies. On the other hand, the big retailers, faced with the increasing support for liberalizing retail, began to recognize that the repeal of RA 1180 was just a matter of time. This realization was expressed publicly, when the two main retail groups in the country— the Philippine Retail Association (PRA) and the Philippine Franchise Association (PFA)— conceded that regime shift was inevitable (Congress of the Philippines 1998).

 Another crucial development in the retail sector was the fragmentation of the big retailers. The big retailers, which for a long time were united in blocking the move to liberalize retail, took diverging positions. For instance, with the perceived inevitability of the repeal of RA 1180, the leading big retailers in the country reluctantly accepted the opening of the sector to foreigners under the condition that the amending law would give emphasis on the strategic partnership (e.g. joint venture) between them and the foreign retailers (Congress of the Philippines 1998). Conversely, other big retailers, specifically, affiliates of Kilusan Tungo sa Pambansang Tangkilikan (KATAPAT) continued to maintain their position of strongly opposing the entry of foreigners in retail (Congress of the Philippines 1998). In this scenario, the retail sector had become divided: the small retailers were all-out for liberalizing retail; the leading big retailers took an open but qualified stand; and the remaining big retailers continued to vehemently go against liberalizing retail. This fragmentation, in effect, was significant since it profoundly weakened their pressure on the government.

Under the conditions discussed, the Eleventh Congress passed RA 8762 in February 2000, officially amending RA 1180 and liberalizing the retail sector. RA 8762 marked a regime shift in the retail sector from a close to an open system. The law, in general, allowed foreign retailers to directly operate and do business in the country. Although regime shift implies drastic policy change, ironically, RA 8762 was conservative in substance. This outcome was mainly due to the several key stipulations that were included in the law which, in effect, considerably watered down the openness of the retail sector. In particular:

(1)   Retail trade enterprises with a paid-up capital of less than $2,500,000.00 are reserved exclusively for Filipino citizens and corporations.

(2)   Foreign investors interested in acquiring shares of existing local retailers may purchase only up to a maximum of 60 percent of the equity within the first two years from the effectivity of the repealing law.

(3)   Retail trade enterprises where foreign ownership exceeds 80 percent must offer a minimum of 30 percent of their equity to Filipinos through any stock exchange in the Philippines within eight years from their start of operations.

(4)   The DTI must prequalify all foreign retailers before they are allowed to conduct business in the Philippines. For instance, to preclude fly-by-night retailers, the DTI requires foreign retailers to have at least five retailing branches in operation anywhere around the world as well as a five-year track record in retailing.

(5)   Only foreign retailers coming from countries that allow the entry of Filipino retailers would be permitted to engage in business.

(6)   At least 30 percent of the stock inventory of foreign retailers, after 10 years from the effectivity of the law, must be Philippine made.

(7)   Qualified foreign retailers are not allowed to use rolling stores or sales representatives, or engage in door-to-door selling or the restaurant business, or run sari-sari stores (see RA 8762, Section 5-10).

The stipulations were concessions made principally to appease the big retailers. In essence, the stipulations provided considerable protection to local retailers and restricted the access of foreigners to the retail sector. These concessions were a strategic move taken in the legislation of RA 8762. They were the primary instrument used by President Estrada and the Congress to placate the opposition of the big retailers in coming up with a liberalizing law consistent with the government’s economic strategy (Congress of the Philippines 2000). Here, the fragmented retail sector was not able to preclude the enactment of the law, but the enduring influence of the big retailers was enough to shape the substance of the law.

The Underlying Factors in the Regime Shifts

Although separated by four decades and having opposite outcomes (a protectionist law [RA 1180] and a liberalizing law [RA 8762]), the two regime shifts in retail, overall, have similar salient factors; particularly, the external-internal impetus, presidential intervention and the changing dynamics in the retail sector. Essentially, these factors defined the policy making process and outcome, and their convergence illustrated the workings of domestic politics in the Philippines. Specifically, the external-internal impetus helped instigate the move for regime shift; the sitting President played a significant role in the success (or not) of the legislation in Congress; and the retail sector (i.e. the segment in the economy directly affected by the regime shifts) exemplified varying dynamics which facilitated the enactment of the laws.

At the onset, the mobilization for regime shift was set off by the external-internal stimulus. In RA 1180, the move for nationalizing the retail sector was traceable to the post-World War 2 global trend. There was a world-wide inclination for newly independent countries to adopt protectionist policies as their main development strategy. In RA 8762, the move for liberalizing the retail sector was induced by the global popularity of the neoliberal economic school in the 1980s. There was a widespread preference for countries (including ASEAN countries) to adopt open market and trade oriented policies as the engine for economic development. These external impetuses coincided with developments on the domestic front. In RA 1180, the longtime hold of the Chinese immigrant retailers on the industry and the emergence of the Filipino business class (i.e. interested in gaining entry into the lucrative retail sector) provided the motivation for the call to nationalize the retail sector. In RA 8762, the stagnation of the economy and the oligopoly in the retail sector supplied the rationale for embracing the liberal economic strategy. On the whole, the external impetus and the domestic dynamics intertwined and worked together in instigating a strong demand for regime shift.

            Since both regime shifts directly involved the interplay and collision of powerful interests, presidential intervention became a crucial element in diluting the resistance in the legislation. In RA 1180, the primary opposition to the move to nationalize the retail sector came from the alien retailers, especially, the Chinese immigrant retailers. The alien retailers were established actors in the domestic economy since they had the financial leverage and were strongly supported by their respective governments. In RA 8762, the main opposition to the move to liberalize the retail sector was the local big retailers. The big retailers were entrenched actors in the domestic arena since they controlled the retail sector, a critical segment of the economy. Here, the action of the alien retailers and the big retailers in opposing the move for regime shift were consistent with the intentions of preserving their dominance in the industry.

Since the regime shift was designed to alter the status quo, the alien retailers and the big retailers saw the move as directly detrimental to them. On this ground, both mobilized and took strong actions against the legislative initiative. Moreover, the resistance of the alien retailers and the big retailers was further aggravated by the presence of collective action dilemma in the policy making equation. In RA 1180, particularly in the early part of the move to nationalize retail, the alien retailers’ organizations were already well-established compared to the Filipino retailers’ organizations which were still emerging. In RA 8762, the consequences of opening retail to foreign competition were perceived as direct and immediate for the big retailers, while the benefits were deemed as highly dispersed and long term for the consumers. These conditions considerably enhanced the mobilization against regime shift, and hence, made the move highly contentious. With these circumstances, the legislation entailed the intervention of the President in offsetting the influence of the oppositions as well as the collective action dilemma. Here, the President’s resolve (i.e. President Magsaysay in RA 1180 and President Estrada in RA 8762) became instrumental in leading Congress to enact the laws.

            Lastly, the varying dynamics in the retail sector became the final component in the attainment of the two regime shifts. In RA 1180, there was consolidation of the retail sector. Since the emerging Filipino business class wanted to move into the lucrative retail industry, they bound together against the alien retailers who controlled the sector. The consolidation of the Filipino business class was critical in the legislation since they were able to counteract the influence of the foreign-government-supported alien retailers, especially, the financially entrenched Chinese immigrant retailers. In turn, this change in the retail sector’s dynamics provided a compelling inducement for the legislators to enact the law. In RA 8762, there was fragmentation in the retail sector. The small retailers, the leading big retailers and the other big retailers took diverging stands on the policy issue. This fragmentation in the retail sector was crucial in the legislation since it considerably weakened the sector’s influence. In turn, the “breaking up” among the key actors of the retail sector afforded the lawmakers the autonomy-leeway to legislate the law. Furthermore, the two regime shifts also exemplified the enduring influence of the retailers (i.e. the Chinese immigrant retailers in RA 1180 and the big retailers in RA 8762). Despite the successful enactment of RA 1180 and RA 8762 (which presupposes drastic change in policy), the two laws were conservative. The final forms of both policies included moderating provisions that were demanded principally by the alien retailers and the big retailers. These necessary concessions were the final straw in completing the legislative process of the regime shifts.

Conclusion and Implications

            In the contemporary globalized era where economic policies, particularly, in trade and finance, are enacted in an international context, the Philippine case of regime shifts for retail exemplifies two key points: first, although the initiative to adopt or change economic regimes for a country will continue to have external impetus, the success of regime shift as well as the substance of its specific policy will be significantly dependent on the workings of domestic politics; and second, the legislative experience characterizes the present-day relationship between global influence and domestic dynamics in policy making.

With regards the first dimension, the initiative for economic regime shift, to a large extent, will continue to have strong exogenous impetuses. This reality has to do with the persistent dominance of the neoliberal orthodoxy in the contemporary globalized era. In the neoliberal world order, economic regimes are typically enforced on a country from the outside via a ‘top-down’ approach. In particular, the global trade and finance institutions set and impose such regimes on governments which, in turn, are compelled to adopt and legislate their prescribed policies. Although this is the “global arrangement,” the realization of economic regime shifts, as well as the actual shape of the policy, is still dependent on the praxis of domestic politics. In other words, the success (or failure) of the initiative and the specific form of its law (e.g. conservative or radical) are largely derivative of the interplay and convergence of the factors peculiar to the country. For instance, the realization and the substance of RA 1180 and RA 8762 were determined by the interface of actors and stakeholders with diverse interests (e.g. the President and the legislators or the fragmentation/consolidation of the business community), the institutional power arrangement (e.g. dominance of the executive over the legislature) and the prevailing condition/timing (e.g. post-World War 2/post-EDSA economic strategy or the need to appease the business interests). The interaction among these variables was critical since it directly played out in the policy making process and ultimately determined the outcome. Thus, understanding why regime shift occurs and how a policy takes its shape is contingent largely in comprehending the complexity/specificities of domestic politics.

The second aspect exemplifies the convergence of globalization and national politics in policy making. Overall, the Philippines’ two cases of regime shifts in retail suggest considering international demand more as a constant and the dynamics of domestic politics more as a variable. External demand is the starting point but once passed through the institutional legislative mill, the policy initiative can take many forms depending on how the domestic politics plays out. This proposition has a huge bearing on conceptualising externally driven top-down policies (which are prevalent today). An initiative that is uniformly imposed from the outside by the global trade and finance institutions, when received, would vary from country to country, depending on the nitty-gritty of the politics on the ground. In other words, it emphasizes the danger of assuming that an internationally prescribed “good” regime or policy would just be identically adopted by different countries. Instead, once an initiative is taken by the government, it is bound to reflect the distinct character of politics practiced on each country. This variation in dynamics leads to engagements and tradeoffs among the domestic variables which ultimately steer the process to different pathways and varieties of results. The discussion puts a caveat on the conventional thinking that economic regimes are firmly embedded in external global impetus, as the consequences of domestic politics continue to exemplify considerable say in determining the policy making process and outcome.

In closing, the finding in this study has considerable implications on retail globalization in Southeast Asia, given the constancy of external impetuses and the variability of domestic politics among countries (i.e. Malaysia, Thailand, Vietnam and Indonesia) in the region. On one hand, the countries are similarly exposed to the same international influences, particularly coming from multilateral institutions active in the region, such as the WTO, the IMF, the WB, APEC and the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN). This condition presupposes a parallel trajectory, overall, among the Southeast Asian countries in terms retail trade policies. On the other hand, the countries, relative to each other, are highly diversified in their social-economic-political contexts. These variations in domestic dynamics are likely to play out in determining the specific retail policies and regulations (i.e. the process of deriving them and defining their substantive form), as these factors would naturally intervene in political processes and would have distinct consequences in each country. With this prospect, this study ends with a call for more research on the politics behind retail policies and regulations among individual countries in Southeast Asia, as this is the only way to ascertain the particular workings of polity on the ground and the extent of their shaping effect.


References

AC Nielsen Study. 2005. Executive Summary on In-Focus: Supermarkets.

Agoncillo, Teodoro . 1990. History of the Filipino People. Quezon City: Garotech Publishing.

Agpalo, Remidio. 1962. The Political Process and the Nationalization of the Retail Trade in the Philippines. Quezon City: Office of Coordinator of Research, U.P. Diliman.

Almonte, Jose. 2007. To Put Our House in Order: We Must Level the Playing Field. Manila: Foundation for Economic Freedom, Inc.

Balassa, Bela. 1981. The Newly Industrializing Countries in the World Economy. Oxford: Pergamon.

Baran, Paul. 1957. The Political Economy of Growth. New York: Monthly Review.

Bardach, Eugene. 2006. Policy Dynamics. In Michael Moran, Martin Rein and Robert Goodin (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

Bello, Walden and Severina Rivera. 1977. Logistics of Repression and Other Essays. Washington, DC: Friends of the Filipino People.

Bracking, Sarah. 1999. Structural Adjustment: Why It Wasn’t Necessary and Why It Didn’t Work. Review of African Political Economy, 26(80): 207-226.

Caoili, Olivia. 2006. The Restored Philippine Congress. In Noel Morada and Teresa Tadem (eds.), Philippine Politics and Governance. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Diliman.

Coe, Neil and Neil Wrigley (eds.). 2009. The Globalization of Retailing. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. ​

Coe, Neil and Yong-Sook Lee. 2006. The Strategic Localization of Transnational Retailers: The Case of Samsung-Tesco in South Korea. Economic Geography, 82(1): 61-88.

Coronel, Sheila, Yvonne Chua, Luz Rimban and Booma Cruz. 2004. The Rulemakers: How the Wealthy and Well-Born Dominate Congress. Quezon City: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee on Commerce and Industry held on February 9, 1954.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee on Commerce and Industry Hearings on the Nationalization of the Retail Trade held on February 23, 1954.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. House of Representatives Congressional Record of Proceedings held on May 19, 1954.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. House of Representatives History of Bills and Resolutions.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. Senate Congressional Record of Proceedings held on May 20, 1954.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. Senate History of Bills and Resolutions.

Congress of the Philippines. 1954. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee on Commerce and Industry Hearings on the Nationalization of the Retail Trade held on February 9, 1954.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on November 10, 19, and 25, 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on December 8, 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the House of Representatives Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on February 4, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript of the Senate Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on August 18 and 25, 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript of the Senate Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on October 9 and 20, 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript of the Senate Committee Hearings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on November 13 and 16, 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the House of Representatives Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on November 16, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the House of Representatives Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on December 6, 7, 8, 9, 13, 14, and 15, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on September 14, 21, 22, and 28, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on October 4, 5, and 6, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on November 10, 15, and 16, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on December 13 and 22, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 153 and House Bill 7602 held on December 15, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript of the Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 153 and House Bill 7602 held on December 17, 1999.

Congress of the Philippines. 2000. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on January 10, 2000.

Congress of the Philippines. 2000. Transcript of the Senate Session Proceedings on Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 1998 held on February 15, 2000.
                       
Congress of the Philippines. 2000. Transcript of the Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 153 and House Bill 7602 held on February 9, 2000.

Constantino, Renato. 1970. Dissent and Counter-Consciousness. Quezon City: Malaya Books.

Constantino, Renato. 1975. The Philippines: A Past Revisited, Volume 1. Quezon City: Renato Constantino - The Foundation for Nationalist Studies.

Cox, Gary and Mathew McCubbins. 2001. The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes. In Stephan Haggard and Mathew McCubbins (eds.), Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

De Dios, Emmanuel. 1990. A Political Economy of Philippine Policy-Making. In John W. Langford and K. Lorne Brownsey (eds.), Economic Policy-Making in the Asia-Pacific Region. Halifax, Nova Scotia: Institute for Research on Public Policy.

De Dios, Emmanuel and Paul Hutchcroft. 2003. Political Economy. In Arsenion Balisacan and Hal Hill (eds.), The Philippine Economy: Development, Policies, and Challenges. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.

Dicken, Peter. 2003. Global Shift: Reshaping the Global Economic Map in the 21st Century. London: Sage.

Dicken, Peter, Philip Kelly, Kris Olds and Henry Wai-Chung Yeung. 2001. Chains and Networks, Territories and Scales: Towards on Analytical Framework for the Global Economy. Global Networks, 1(2): 89-112.

Frank, Andre Gunder. 1967. Capitalism and Underdevelopment. New York: Monthly Review.

Garrett, Geoffrey. 2000. Globalization and National Autonomy. In Ngaire Woods (ed.), The Political Economy of Globalization. London: Macmillan Press Ltd.

Gray, John. 1998. False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism. London: Granta.

Greider, William. 1997. One World, Ready or Not. New York: Simon and Schuster.

Gutierrez, Ben Paul. 2010. Shopping Problems of Urban Filipino Customers. Annual BSPUP Professorial Chair Lectures 15–17 February 2010. http://www.bsp.gov.ph/events/pcls/ downloads/2010/BSP_2a_gutierrez.pdf

Gutierrez, Eric. 1994. The Ties that Bind: A Guide to Family, Business and Other Interests in the Ninth House of Representatives. Pasig: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism.

Hay, Colin. 2006. Globalization and Public Policy. In Michael Moran, Martin Rein and Robert Goodin (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hayek, Friedrich. 1990. The Constitution of Liberty. London: Routledge.

Held, David and Anthony McGrew, David Goldblatt and Jonathan Perraton. 1999. Global Transformations: Politics, Economics and Culture. Cambridge: Polity.

Henderson, Jeffrey, Peter Dicken, Martin Hess, Neil Coe and Henry Wai-Chung Yeung. 2002. Global Production Networks and the Analysis of Economic Development. Review of International Political Economy, 36(9): 436-464.

Howlett, Michael and M Ramesh. 1995. Studying Public Policy: Policy Cycles and Policy Subsystems. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hutchcroft, Paul. 1993. Selective Squander: The Politics of Preferential Credit Allocation in the Philippines. In Stephan Haggard, Chung H. Lee, and Sylvia Maxfield (eds.), The Politics of Finance in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Hutchroft, Paul. 1998. Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Ithaca: Cornel University Press.

Jison, Arsenio. 1954. Some Problems of the Filipino Retailers. Voice of the Retailers, December(1) 24.

Lal, Deepak. 1983. The Poverty of Development Economics. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

Leftwich, Adrian. 2000. States of Development: On the Primacy of Politics in Development. Cambridge: Polity Press.

Lichauco, Alejandro. 1973. The Lichauco Paper: Imperialism in the Philippines. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Martinez-Santos, Gloria. 2000. The Congresses of the Third Republic 1946-1972. In Cesar Pobre (ed), Philippines Legislature 100 Years. Quezon City: New Day Publisher.

Montes, Manuel. 1992. The Politics of Liberalization: The Aquino Government’s 1990 Tariff Reform Initiative. In David Timberman (ed.), The Politics of Economic Reform in Southeast Asia. Makati: Asian Institute of Management.

Nurkse, Ragnar. 1961. Balanced and Unbalanced Growth. In Gottfried Haberler and Robert Stern (eds.), Equilibrium and Growth in the World Economy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

O’Brien, Richard. 1992. Global Financial Integration: The End of Geography. London: Royal Institute for International Affairs.

Olsen, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Ohmae, Kenichi. 1996. The End of the Nation State: The Rise of Regional Economics. London: HarperCollins.

Patalinghug, Epictetus. 1996. Philippine Privatization: Experience, Issues and Lessons. Quezon City: UP Center for Integrative and Development Studies.

Philippines Special Report. 2002. Retailing in the Philippines. MCA Limited.

Prebisch, Raul. The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations.

Reed, David (ed.) 1992. Structural Adjustment and the Environment. London: Earthscan.

Reich, Michael. 2002. The Politics of Reforming Health Policies. http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/ pubmed/12731117

Reich, Robert. 1991. The Work of Nations: Preparing Ourselves for 21st-Century Capitalism. New York: Knof.

Republic Act 1180. An Act to Regulate the Retail Business.

Republic Act 8762. Retail Trade Liberalization Act of 2000.

Reyes, Teofilo. 1955. Our Pressing Economic Problems. Filipino Trade Views, March(1) 12.

Sang, Chul Choi. 2003. Moves into the Korean Market by Global Retailers and Responses of Local Retailers'. In John Dawson, Masao Mukoyama, Chul Choi Sang and Roy Larke (eds.), The Internationalisation of Retailing in Asia. London: RoutledgeCurzon.

Schirmer, Daniel and Stephen Shalom. 1987. Independence with Strings. In Daniel Schirmer and Stephen Shalom (eds.), The Philippines Reader: A History of Colonialism, Neocolonialism, Dictatorship, and Resistance. Quezon City: Ken Incorporated.

Shugart, Mathew and Stephan Haggard. 2001. Institutions and Public Policy in Presidential Systems. In Stephan Haggard and Mathew McCubbins (eds.), Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Simon, David.1995. Debt, Democracy and Development in Africa in the 1990s. In David Simon, Wim Van Spengen, Chris Dixon and Anders Narman (eds.), Structurally Adjusted Africa: Poverty, Debt and Basics Needs. London: Pluto Press.

Sorensen, Georg. 2006. The Transformation of the State. In Colin Hay, Michael Lister and David Marsh (eds.), The State: Theories and Issues. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Stein, Ernesto, Mariano Tommasi, Koldo Echebarria, Eduardo Lora, and Mark Payne. 2005. The Politics of Policies: Economic and Social Progress in Latin America, 2006 Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

Stewart, Joseph, David Hedge and James Lister. 2008. Public Policy: An Evolutionary Approach. Boston: Thomson Wadsworth.
Tansey, Stephen. 1995. Politics: The Basics. London: Routlege.

Tilly, Chris. 2007. Wal-Mart and Its Workers: NOT the Same All Over the World. Connecticut Law Review, 39(4): 1805-1823.

Tokatli, Nebahat and Yonca Boyaci Eldener. 2002. Globalization and the Changing Political Economy of Distribution Channels in Turkey. Environment and Planning A, 34(2): 217-238.

Toye, John. 1993. Dilemmas of Development. Oxford: Blackwell.

Tsebelis, George. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. http://www.nyu.edu/gsas/dept/politics/seminars/tsebelis

Velasco, Renato. 2006. Parties, Elections, and Democratization in Post-Martial Law Philippines. In Noel Morada and Teresa Tadem (eds.), The Philippine Politics and Governance. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Diliman.

Wade, Robert. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Wang, Shuguang. 2003. Internationalisation of Retailing in China. In John Dawson, Masao Mukoyama, Chul Choi Sang and Roy Larke (eds.), The Internationalisation of Retailing in Asia. London: RoutledgeCurzon.

Weiss, Linda.1998. The Myth of the Powerless State. Cambridge: Polity.

Wood, Angela.1997. The International Monetary Fund’s Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility: What Role for Development? http://www.brettonwoodsproject.org/brief/esaf.html

Woods, Ngaire. 2000. Globalization and International Institutions. In Ngaire Woods (ed.), The Political Economy of Globalization. London: Macmillan Press Ltd.

Wrigley, Neil, Neil Coe and Andrew Currah. 2005. Globalizing Retail: Conceptualizing the Distribution-based TNC. Progress in Human Geography, 29(4): 437-457.

Yeung, Henry Wai-Chung. 2005. Rethinking Relational Economic Geography. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 30(1): 37-51.







[1]Dr. Brillo is Associate Professor at the Institute for Governance and Rural Development, University of the Philippines Los Ban͂os. This article benefited from the previous works of the author on the policy making dynamics in the Philippines.
[2] As of 2012, the Philippine Retailers Association reported that the retail sector accounted for 15 percent of GDP and employed 5 million Filipinos or 18 percent of the workforce.
[3] Some families who became prosperous during that time were the Aranetas, the Puyats, the Roxases, the Aguinaldos, and the Halilis (Agpalo 1962).
[4] The First National Assembly (1935-1938) and the Second National Assembly (1938-1941).
[5] The First Congress (1946-1949) and the Second Congress (1949-1953).
[6] The CGCC was founded in 1904, and the FCCC had 227-member chambers of commerce throughout the country (Agpalo 1962).
[7] The Bell Trade Act of 1946 was subsequently replaced by Laurel-Langley Agreement in 1955.
[8] Sari-sari stores capture only 30% of retail sales but account for 90% of the universe of stores (AC Nielsen 2005, Gutierrez 2010).

No comments: