Thursday, May 9, 2013

A Story of Re-Legislating Policies: The Politics of Policy Modification in the Philippines

Bing Baltazar C. Brillo[1]

2012   Philippine Quarterly of Culture and Society, vol. 39, no. 2, pp. 163-183.

Abstract

Policy modification is an area of policy change least explored, as most of the scholarly outputs have concentrated on policy shift. As a legislative process, policy modification refers to the re-legislation of a recently enacted statute in a relatively short period of time to rectify or adjust it to some domestic or external demand in the political system. This definition presupposes two dimensions: first, an initial law is passed by the legislature; and second, after a relatively short span of time, the policy is amended in response to some post-enactment request, petition, or pressure. Moreover, the legislative action entails continuity since the aim is merely to improve or enhance the existing policy due to some post-enactment demand, and not to reverse or drastically change the overall make-up of the policy. This study analyzes three cases of statutory re-legislations— the Foreign Investment Act (R.A. 7042 to R.A. 8179), the Anti-Dumping Act (R.A. 7843 to R.A. 8752), and the Anti-Money Laundering Act (R.A. 9160 to R.A. 9194)—  to empirically verify and substantiate the assumptions in literature as well as illustrate the intricacies of policy modifications in the Philippines. The paper contends that the policy modification  of the three cases can be elucidated through the following: first, the FIA as internally driven via government learning; second, the ADA by the interplay of domestic strategy and external dynamics; and lastly, the AMLA as externally driven via coercive measures.


Introduction

 In the last decade, the bulk of scholarship in Philippine policy making has revolved around the dynamics of substantive policy formulation and change. For instance: Antonio Pedro and Eric Batalla assessed the politics of banking and financial liberalization (Republic Act [R.A.] 7721) in 2002; Lourdes Rebullida discussed the dynamics between the urban poor and the government in formulation of the housing policy (R.A. 7279) in 2003; Jorge Tigno examined the legislation dynamics of the migrant workers and overseas Filipino law (R.A. 8042) in 2004; Ela Atienza evaluated the effects of the devolution of the health policy (R.A. 7160) in 2004; Amado Mendoza analyzed the politics behind the legislation of the comprehensive tax reform program (R.A. 8424) in 2005; and Bing Baltazar Brillo examined the intricacies of the evolution of the retail trade policy (R.A. 8762) in 2010;[2] and reexamined the quality of pluralism that existed among actors and stakeholders in the legislation of the foreign bank liberalization law (R.A. 7721) in 2012.[3] Although the literature has sufficiently explored substantive policy formulation and change; one form of policy change, specifically policy modification, has largely been ignored by scholars.[4]

Policy modification simply refers to the re-legislation of a recently passed statute in a relatively short span of time in order to rectify or adjust the policy to some domestic or external demand in the political system. In other words, policy modification involves the fine-tuning of a recently legislated policy in order to make it more suitable for the intended purpose or more compliant to the changing environment. As a legislative process, policy modification has two dimensions— first, the enactment of the initial law; and second, the eventual revision of the same law within a short period of time. Policy modification also presupposes the continuity of the policy. The aim of the legislative action is simply to improve or enhance the existing statute due to some post-enactment demand, and not to reverse or drastically change the overall make-up of the policy.

This study seeks to fill the gap in literature by elucidating the dynamics of policy modification. In particular, the paper provides empirical discussions on why and how policy modifications come about as well as its subtleties in the Philippine setting. In doing so, it examines three legislative cases of policy modifications: the Foreign Investment Act (R.A. 7042 to R.A. 8179), the Anti-Dumping Act (R.A. 7843 to R.A. 8752), and the Anti-Money Laundering Act (R.A. 9160 to R.A. 9194). The cases were selected since the statutes fit the dimensions of policy modification— that is after the enactment of the original law, the statutes were re-legislated in a relatively short period of time with the sole purpose of “adjusting” the said law. The statutes also share a common denominator since all of them are outcomes of the post-EDSA governments’ adaptation to the global liberalization trend. Furthermore, the paper serves as a sequel to the previous research of the author, where the policy making of the initial laws— specifically, the Foreign Investment Act (FIA), the Anti-Dumping Act (ADA), and the Anti-Money Laundering Act (AMLA)— has been previously studied (see Brillo 2010b; Brillo 2011; Brillo 2012b). Thus, this paper intends to complete the analysis by focusing on the area least explored— the post-enactment to the amendment phase of the legislative process.

Two Forms of Policy Change: Policy Shift and Policy Modification

            As an analytical concept, policy change was brought to light only in the late1980s in the realm of policy studies. In modern political systems, probing on policy change is essential, as policies are constantly evolving and rarely maintained in exactly the same form over time (Peters 1986). This reality, hence, makes the politics of changing policy commonplace among governments. Hogwood and Gunn (1984) cited three reasons why policy change is frequent in contemporary legislation. First, the expansion of government activities through the years brings about overlap in policies which would necessitate reforming existing policies. Second, legislative oversight, particularly in cases of inadequacies and adverse side effects, may instigate the changing of the policies. And third, the demands of sustainable economic growth and the implications of the financial commitment of a government might require the replacement of old policies. Although prevalent, policy change is always a difficult legislative undertaking since it is always easier to continue an existing policy than to replace or reform it (Howlett and Ramesh 1995).This is expected, as people benefiting from the status quo policy would naturally oppose any move to change the policy.

Broadly, policy change refers to “the point at which a policy is evaluated and redesigned so that the entire policy process begins anew” (Stewart et al. 2008: 11). Policy change takes two forms: first is policy shift where the make-up of the prevailing policy is substantially altered or replaced; and second is policy modification where the existing policy is merely adjusted or reformed (see Anderson 1990; Howlett and Ramesh 1995; Stewart, Hedge and Lester 2008; Brillo 2010a). Relative to policy modification, policy shift has been sufficiently studied in both its empirical and theoretical aspects. For instance, on the empirical side—studies explaining the pattern of policy shift in American politics. Schlesinger (1986), stated that policy reforms happen in a regular cyclical alternation between the two dominant political parties— the Democratic Party and the Republican Party. While Amenta and Skocpol (1989), argued that policy shifts occur in an erratic pattern among groups in society since policies of one period which favor one group, serve as stimulus for a reaction in the next period which would favor another group.

On the theoretical side— studies explaining policy shift by means of analytical frameworks. Sabatier (1987 and 1988) and Jenkins-Smith (1999), via their advocacy coalition framework, concluded that policy shift occurs mainly through the competition among advocacy coalitions and through external changes in the policy subsystem (e.g., shift in socio-economic orientation, public opinion, or governing coalitions). Here, advocacy coalition refers to alliances of groups (usually consisting of legislators, bureaucrats, interest groups, and think tanks) with shared beliefs that coordinate actions to push for a particular policy (Sabatier and Jenkins-Smith 1999). Another, Baumgartner and Jones (1991 and 1993), through their punctuated equilibrium framework, argued that policy shift happens when the prevailing policy monopoly in a political system is “punctuated” (i.e. challenged and successfully replaced) by a new one. Here, policy monopoly refers to “a set of structural arrangements that keep policy making in the hands of relatively small group of interested policy actors” (Smith and Larimer 2009: 84). In a political system, policy monopoly is usually broken when there is a redefinition of issue (e.g., positive to negative image) since this leads to the alteration of a policy subsystem. And Kingdon (1995), utilizing his three streams framework, contended that, to have a successful policy shift, certain phases must come together. First, the problem stream where the problem is highlighted and moved to the government agenda. Second, the policy stream where alternative policies vis-à-vis the problem is generated. And third, the political stream where the key actors and stakeholders “bargain” over the policy. Here, all three streams must converge to open a policy window for policy shift.

Oddly, policy modification, which is the more typical form of policy change— as it is easier to make adjustments and continue a policy than substantially change a policy— has been scantily explored. Policy modification, as a policy making process, refers to the re-legislation of a recently enacted statute in a relatively short period of time to rectify or adjust it to some domestic or external demand in the political system. The definition presupposes two dimensions of policy modification. First, an initial law is passed by the legislature (usually resulting in a policy shift, as this law substantially alters or replaces the old policy). Second, after a relatively short span of time, the enacted law is amended in response to some post-enactment request, petition, or pressure. Here, the initial law is fine-tuned in the re-legislation to improve or make the policy more suitable or compliant to a national or international demand. Broadly, the demand to rework the policy can come from a multitude of factors, such as error in legislation, ineffectiveness of enforcement, revelation of unintended consequences, changes in the environment, or international pressure. Furthermore, unlike policy shift which substantially changes the direction or essence of the statute, policy modification presupposes the continuity of the existing policy despite the amendment or revision to it.

Among the policy shift’s frameworks, the closest in explaining policy modification is the advocacy coalition framework via its concept of policy learning. In general, policy learning refers to a condition where the policy actors (governmental, stakeholders and coalitions) continually update their beliefs in response to new information and changes in the political, socio-economic environment (Heclo 1974, Sabatier 1988, May 1992, Hall 1993, and Rist 1994). The literature on policy learning provides two directions that are akin to policy modifications. On one hand, policy learning is equated to a government’s normal process where decision-makers attempt to improve the policy or to understand policy failures based on new information and/or past consequences (Hall 1993). On the other hand, policy learning is deemed as a governmental activity where decision-makers adjust or revise a policy in response to an external stimuli or changes in the environment (Heclo 1974). Taken together, the grounds for the occurrence of policy modification can be inferred as a function of two sources— internal learning and external changes. In other words, policy modification, as a legislative process, can originate either from within (based on internal dynamics among the governmental or societal actors) or from outside (based on externally driven inducements or pressure from international actors) of the political system. Taking off from the preceding discussions, this study analyzes three cases of statutory re-legislations. The aim is to empirically verify and substantiate the assumptions in literature as well as illustrate the intricacies of policy modifications in the Philippines.

 The Foreign Investment Law (R.A. 7042 to R.A. 8179)

R.A. 7042 or the Foreign Investment Act (FIA) was formally signed into law by President Corazon Aquino on the 13 June 1991. The FIA was conceived when the Congressional Executive Investment Policy Review (CEIPR) set up from November 1989 to February 1990 concluded that most of the investment laws of the country are outdated and needed immediate revisions (Brillo 2012b). Specifically, the CEIPR was referring to Executive Order 226, otherwise known as Book II of the Omnibus Investment Code of 1987,[5] a law largely taken from R.A. 5186 and R.A. 5455 which were enacted in 1967 and 1968, respectively. The law was considered passé and discordant with the country’s present economic situation particularly in the contemporary era of economic globalization. The CEIPR’s assessment reflected the neoliberal orientation of the Aquino administration. This position was clearly articulated by the Board of Investments (BOI): those policies to be adopted “should reflect the desire of this government to open up the economy… that is outworld-oriented, (with) a broader base of participation, and with minimum government intervention” (Congress of the Philippines-Senate Committee Hearings on Foreign Investments of 1991: 3).

The FIA was the foremost of the package of legislative measures adopted by the Aquino administration to improve the country’s overall investment climate. The policy was designed to have a spillover effect since its passage was expected to precipitate the legislation of other policies that would further liberalize the economy. In particular, the FIA was intended to address the insufficiency in the capital investment of the country which should ideally be generated through internal savings. Since the Philippines has a low domestic savings rate, the government was compelled to explore external sources such as foreign loans and foreign investments. Foreign loans, however, was not an appealing alternative as the country at the time was already burdened by a huge foreign debt amounting to $28 billion. Thus, in resolving the country’s capital deficiency, the only viable option of the Aquino administration was attracting foreign investments (Brillo 2012b). Under this condition, the Aquino administration impelled the Eighth Congress to immediately enact the foreign investment law.

Four years afterwards, the Ramos administration called on the Congress to repeal the FIA. The objective of the amendment was to further liberalize the entry of foreign investment in the country. Since the implementation of the FIA, the government believed that the policy was relatively successful in increasing the flow of investments in the economy. For instance, Senator Ramon Masaysay Jr. cited in his sponsorship speech that “for the years 1993-94, a 403 percent or more than four times jump in foreign equity investments of BOI-approved projects was realized when the actual figures rose from P14.414 billion in 1993 to P97.781 billion in 1994. The trend continued with the period covering the first semester of 1994 to 1995, which showed a remarkable 53.08% increase in investment over that of the previous year” (Congress of the Philippines-Senate Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991: 9). Despite this, the consensus among the government agencies, such as the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP), National Economic Development Authority (NEDA), Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Department of Trade and Industry (DTI), and BOI, was that there is a necessity to amend the FIA so as to maximize its benefits. As stated by Congressman Margarito Teves, one of the sponsors of the repealing bill, “unfortunately, the opportunities offered by the new law was not competitive enough to attract substantial foreign capital… from 1991 to 1993, the country attracted only $1.5B or 6% out of some $25.3B foreign direct investments in Southeast Asia”[6] (Congress of the Philippines-House of Representatives Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991: 135). Here, the success of neighboring ASEAN countries was attributed largely to their more liberal investment policies. Thus, the logic formed was that to be at par with them, there is an urgent need to amend and improve the FIA.

            The move to amend the R.A. 7042 revolved around three substantive provisions. First, the deletion of the three-year requirement before a domestic enterprise may change its status to an export enterprise. Second, the reduction of the minimum paid-in capital requirement from $500,000 to $150,000. And third, the removal/retention of the provisions relating to the Negative List C[7] (Congress of the Philippines-Senate and House of Representatives Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991). Except for the last provision, there was concurrence between the two legislative chambers. The legislation of FIA was facilitated by its initial success. It alleviated the fear that foreign competition would overwhelm the domestic industries— as this apprehension did not happen. As a consequence, this psychological fear, which was a critical factor in the deliberation of the FIA in 1991, was removed from the equation in the re-legislation. The legislation was further accelerated since the FIA was included as an integral part of the Ramos administration’s overall development program of liberalizing the economy. Hence, the government exerted strong efforts to expedite the legislative proceedings by elevating the status of the FIA’s amendment over other policy agenda in Congress. Under this context, the Tenth Congress formally enacted R.A. 8179 which was signed into law by President Fidel Ramos on 28 March 1996.

The Anti-Dumping Law (R.A. 7843 to R.A. 8752)

            R.A. 7843 or the Anti-Dumping Act (ADA) was signed into law by President Fidel Ramos on 21 December 1994. The ADA was enacted by the Ninth Congress principally to preempt the perceived detrimental effects of the implementation of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade—Uruguay Round (GATT-UR) agreement in which the Philippine Government was a signatory. As an economic regime, the GATT-UR, which in 1995 became the World Trade Organization (WTO), promoted the unhampered flow of goods and impelled the country to open its economy. The opening of the domestic market and international trade were promoted mainly through the drastic reduction of tariffs and duties on imported goods. The rationale was that the entry of foreign producers and imported goods would infuse competition and efficiency in the economy. This economic arrangement, however, has a downside. It posed a clear and present danger to the local industries since there was a strong possibility of dumping in the domestic market (Brillo 2010b). Dumping is considered an unfair trade practice when foreign producers, in their quest to penetrate and capture a market share, deliberately flood the domestic market with products that are priced either lower in their own national markets or below the cost of production. The intent here is to artificially lower the price to reduce or eliminate competition. With this looming possibility, GATT-WTO encouraged their member countries to legislate an anti-dumping law for protection. The law was designed as a correcting mechanism where the government is given the right to adopt measures (e.g., imposition of tariffs or duties) to protect the domestic producers against unfair trade practices from foreign producers. Under this circumstance, the Ramos administration and the Ninth Congress agreed to repeal Section 301 of the Tariff and Customs Code of 1957 (R.A. 1937) and legislate an anti-dumping law.

The circumstance behind the policy making of the ADA was unusual. Although the legislation was instigated by the GATT-UR agreement, the ADA was enacted primarily to respond to domestic demand rather than to diligently comply with the GATT-WTO mandate. The ADA was deliberately passed before the formal Senate ratification of GATT-UR agreement. This move was strategic since the objective was to provide adequate protection to domestic industries before the effectivity of the international trade agreement. As aptly stated by Senator Gloria Arroyo, a co-sponsor of the anti-dumping bill, the foremost intent of enacting the law is to set up a safety net to help local industry and only secondarily to comply with the GATT mandate (Congress of the Philippines-Senate Committee Hearings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1994). The lawmakers’ strategy was twofold: first, to overlook some requirements of the GATT-UR agreement in legislating ADA so as to give ample protection to the local businesses; and second, to subsequently re-legislate the law (after maximizing the “grace period” allowed) to fully comply with the anti-dumping provisions of the international treaty. As observed by Brillo (2010b: 22): “The intent of the legislators was to quickly enact an anti-dumping law tilted toward the domestic industry before the formal ratification of the GATT-UR Agreement, and to amend the law again after several years to make it consistent with the commitments to GATT.” Thus, from the very beginning, ADA was intended to be a “temporary” law to maximize benefits for domestic industries with the pre-plan of amending it later on.

Four years afterwards, the Estrada administration and Congress became aware of approaching end of the minimum five-year time table allowed by GATT-WTO for member countries to strictly comply with its anti-dumping requirements. As a consequence, the Legislative-Executive Development Advisory Council (LEDAC) in mid-1998 made the repeal of ADA a priority measure. In Congress, the principal concern of the re-legislation was the issue of conformity— that is how to align the domestic law with the GATT-WTO agreement on Anti-Dumping Practices (Brillo 2010b). As stated by Senator Juan Ponce Enrile, the principal sponsor of the repealing bill and the Chair of the Ways and Means Committee, there is a need to recast R.A. 7843 to make it clearer, simpler to implement and closely adhere to the mandates of GATT-WTO which the Senate ratified (Congress of the Philippines-Senate Committee Hearing on the Anti Dumping Act of 1998). The Tariff Commission (TC), through Commissioner Anthony Abad, identified the provisions of ADA that were inconsistent with the GATT-WTO requirements:

·         withholding of the release of questioned importation pending the determination of a  prima facie case of dumping;
·         imposition of a provisional measure immediately upon the finding of a prima facie case, effective up to the final determination of dumping;
·         inclusion of substitutes in the definition of like products;
·         country-specific application of anti-dumping duty;
·         limiting the period of submission of replies to a questionnaire to 10 days; and
·         retroactive application of definitive anti-dumping duty on all importations within 150 days immediately preceding the filing of the protest (Congress of the Philippines-Senate and House of Representatives Committee Hearings on the Anti-Dumping Act of 1998).

The Estrada administration, knowing well the repercussions from the international community if the government will not honor its commitment, fully supported the move to repeal the existing anti-dumping law. Under this context, the Eleventh Congress deliberated and enacted R.A. 8752 which was formally signed into law by President Joseph Estrada on 12 August 1999.

The Anti-Money Laundering Law (R.A. 9160 to R.A. 9194)

            R.A. 9160 or the Anti-Money Laundering Act (AMLA) was enacted on the 29 September 2001, after a record-breaking deliberation of a little over a month and one day before the deadline set by the Financial Action Task Force (FATF). The FATF is the principal international body that promoted the adoption and development of the anti-money laundering law among countries. The AMLA is a financial regulation policy designed to specifically combat the global proliferation of illicit money— drug and terrorist financing— in banks and other financial institutions. The move that successfully enacted the AMLA began in August 2001 during the Twelfth Congress, roughly a little over 30 days before the FATF’s imposed deadline. The accelerated phase of the legislation in Congress was attributed to the “intervention” of the FATF via the black list or the Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories (NCCT) initiative (Brillo 2011). In the 2000 and 2001 NCCT Reports, the Philippines was identified as one of the 23 countries not complying with the FATF’s financial regulations standard (see FATF 2000 and 2001). As a consequence of being a blacklisted country, the Philippines was subjected to routine countermeasures and given until 30 September 2001 to legislate an anti-money laundering law. FATF also warned that if the Arroyo administration fails to do so within the deadline the country could face severe sanctions from the international financial community. Hence, under this condition, the Arroyo Administration and the Twelfth Congress closely collaborated to pass the anti-money laundering law within the required deadline.

Not long after the effectivity of AMLA, however, there were indications that the law did not fully satisfy the global standards. The FATF pointed out that some stipulations in the law were inconsistent with the 49 + 9 Recommendations which is the international standard for money laundering laws. As observed in the June 2002 NCCT Report:

1.      Although the Philippines’ authorities interpret the regulations as requiring the reporting of all suspicious transactions, this nevertheless conflicts with the AMLA, which only requires reporting of high threshold suspicious transactions.
2.      The law allows the AMLC to access account information upon a court order, but a major loophole remains in that secrecy provisions still protect banking deposits made prior to 17 October 2001. Secrecy provisions also still restrict bank supervisor’s access to account information (FATF 2002: 14).

Accordingly, the need to modify the AMLA was confirmed by Vicente Aquino, the Executive Director of the newly created Anti-Money Laundering Council (AMLC). He revealed that the FATF’s major concerns are the following: first, the threshold was too high and should be lowered to the equivalent of US $10,000.00 or roughly P500,000.00 in Philippine currency; second, although incorporated in the implementing rules and regulations, the suspicious transaction reporting requirement was not included in the law; third, the AMLC lacked the authority to inquire into or examine bank accounts or investments without the order of a competent court; and fourth, bank deposits and transactions prior to the effectivity of the law may be examined for the purpose of investigation and not for the purpose of prosecution (Congress of the Philippines-Senate and House of Representatives Committee Hearings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act 2002).

The inconsistencies in AMLA were brought about by the insistence of some lawmakers to disregard the FATF guidelines. This attitude in Congress, in general, was a reflection of either an ultranationalist sentiment, acts catering to vested interest, or a compromise with opposing lawmakers for them to agree to pass the bill (Brillo 2011). For instance, the most blatant deviation in R.A. 9160 was the threshold requirement. Both the Senators and the Congressmen cited that the FATF’s $10,000.00 (P500,000.00) threshold for reporting suspicious transactions is unacceptable. Instead, the Senators (proposing $3 million) and the Congressmen (proposing $5 million) compromised and agreed to a $4 million threshold, an amount way above the FATF ceiling. With these inconsistencies, the FATF called upon the Philippine Government to take the necessary steps to amend the AMLA so as to conform to the 40 + 9 international standard. The strong determination of the FATF was manifested when the call was accompanied by an advisory that noncompliance would result in countermeasures and retention of the blacklisted status of the country. The FATF insisted, to avoid sanctions and for the country to be delisted, that the appropriate legislative modifications must be made on or before 15 March 2003 (FATF 2003).

The FATF’s demand was taken seriously by the Arroyo administration and the leadership in Congress. On the part of the legislators, it was aptly expressed by Senator Ramon Magsaysay, the Chairman of the Committee on Banks, Financial Institutions and Currencies: “we remain in the list of non-cooperative countries and territories, NCCT, for failure of the Philippines to comply with the recommendations of the FATF, hence, the need to amend our present law so that countermeasures will not be imposed” (Congress of the Philippines-Senate Committee Hearings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act 2002: 8). On the part of the administration, AMLC Executive Director warned that unless the current AMLA is modified, drastic countermeasures would be imposed by FATF and that these sanctions would have severe repercussions considering the Philippine economy is primarily dependent on foreign exchange remittances of Filipino migrant workers. Under this context, the move to formally amend the AMLA began in 2002 in the Twelfth Congress and concluded in 7 March 2003 when the President signed R.A. 9194 into law.

Analysis and Conclusion

Going back to the concept of policy learning, policy modification, as a legislative process, was presumed as a function of internal learning and external changes of the political system. Empirically, this meant that the repealing legislation can either be instigated or managed domestically (by actors such as politicians, bureaucrats, or interest groups) or externally (by actors such as foreign governments, multilateral institutions, or international treaties/regimes). Taking cue from the preceding inference, the analysis of the statutory re-legislations of the FIA, the ADA, and the AMLA reveals the following.

First, the case of the FIA involved policy modification that can be characterized as internally driven via government learning. The re-legislation from R.A. 7042 to R.A. 8179 was prompted principally by the government’s pursuit of its ambitious economic development program. The Ramos administration, under the banner Philippines 2000, was determined to accelerate the liberalization of the economy (De Dios and Hutchcroft 2003; Almonte 2007). As one of the forefront liberalization policy, the FIA was reevaluated. The Ramos administration’s technocrats observed that R.A. 7042 since its implementation in 1991 has been showing inroads in terms of the inflow of foreign investments. The downside, however, was that compared to the inflow of foreign investments in other ASEAN countries, the country was still lagging behind and getting a measly share. This fact was the consensus, as the Ramos administration and Congress conceded that despite the FIA, the capital flowing in the ASEAN region was still bypassing the Philippines (Congress of the Philippines-Senate and House of Representatives Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991).The government technocrats, as a remedy, suggested the immediate repeal of the FIA to enhance the inflow of foreign investment in the country. Their thinking was that relative to other ASEAN countries, the FIA was still restrictive and hence, needed to further liberalize to facilitate the entry of foreign capital. Thus, the legislation experience showed that the government’s evaluation of the existing policy as well as its assessment of the performance of neighboring countries served as the main impetus for the amendment of the FIA.

Second, the case of the ADA involved policy modification characterized by the interplay of domestic strategy and external dynamics. The move to amend from R.A. 7843 to R.A. 8752 was prompted by two attendant circumstances. First was the Ninth Congress’ preplanned action to deliberately legislate a “temporary” law. And second was the Estrada administration’s decision to conform to the GATT-WTO terms on anti-dumping practices. During the Ramos administration, the Ninth Congress hurriedly legislated R.A. 7843 before the Senate ratification of the GATT-WTO treaty. The intent of the legislature was strategic— to enact a law that provides an ample safety net to the domestic industries (even though it does not measure up to the GATT-WTO agreement), and to revise it later when the need arises (that is once the GATT-WTO demands it). Here, the action was premeditated to give local businesses some advantages and protection for a certain period of time. Hence, when the allowable “grace period” was to lapse, expectedly the Estrada administration and the Eleventh Congress took up the cudgels in re-legislating the ADA so as to fully comply with the GATT-WTO mandate. Thus, in this regard, both the lawmakers’ earlier orchestrated strategic action as well as the government’s later action in fulfillment of its international commitment defined the amendment of the ADA.

            And lastly, the case of the AMLA involved policy modification that can be characterized as externally driven via coercive measures. The repeal from R.A. 9160 to R.A. 9194 was primarily instigated by a multilateral institution; the FATF employing direct pressures was able to persuade the government to amend the AMLA. From the very beginning, there was strong resistance among the lawmakers in legislating R.A. 9160. As a consequence, compromises were necessary to enact the law. These concessions resulted in the inclusion of provisions inconsistent with the 40 + 9 Recommendations which is the global standard for money laundering laws. From this, the move to repeal the AMLA commenced when the FATF issued a formal plea to the Arroyo administration. The FATF’s demand, same in its previous plea (in R.A. 9160), was accompanied by the following: first, a definite deadline on when to enact the amendment; second, a statement that the country would continue to be blacklisted unless appropriate action was taken; and third, a warning that countermeasures would be enforced if the no action was taken by the government. The FATF’s threat was overwhelming since it was enough to overcome the intense inertia from some lawmakers in Congress. Consequently, the leadership of the Twelfth Congress and the Arroyo administration, fearing the possibility of severe repercussions in the financial sector and the economy, worked hand in hand to ensure the amendment and conformity of the AMLA within the prescribed deadline. Thus, the story of the legislation and modification of the AMLA is all about the FATF’s demand, deadline, and threat of sanctions.

Summing up, these re-legislation cases illustrate the different dimensions (as well as the subtleties) of policy modification in the Philippines— the FIA as internally driven via government learning; the ADA by the interplay of domestic strategy and external dynamics; and the AMLA as externally driven via coercive measures.


References

Almonte, Jose. 2007. To Put Our House in Order: We Must Level the Playing Field. Manila: Foundation for Economic Freedom, Inc.

Amenta, Edwin and Theda Skocpol. 1989. Taking Exception: Explaining the Distinctiveness of American Public Policies in the Last Century. In F.G. Castles (ed.), The Comparative History of Public Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

Anderson, James. 1990. Public Policymaking: An Introduction. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

Atienza, Ma. Ela. 2004. The Politics of Health Devolution in the Philippines: Experiences of Municipalities in a Devolved Set-up. Philippine Journal of Political Science, 25(48) 25-54.

Batalla, Eric. 2002. The Politics of Financial Liberalization. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization: Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco Center/DLSU.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2010a. The Nationalization and Liberalization of the Retail Trade Industry in the Philippines. Danyag: Journal of Humanities and Social Sciences, 15(1) 55-67.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2010b. The Politics of the Anti-Dumping Law of the Philippines. UPLB Journal, 8(1), 17-29.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2011. Policy Decisiveness, Public Regardedness, and Unity of Purpose: The FATF and the Policy Making Process for AMLA. Asia Pacific Social Science Review Journal, 11(1) 79-102.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2012a. Assessing the Pluralism in Philippine Polity: The Policy Making of the Foreign Bank Liberalization Act (still unpublished).

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2012b. Bureaucrats and Politicians in Policy Making: The Case of the Foreign Investment Act of the Philippines (still unpublished).

Baumgartner, Frank and Bryan Jones. 1991. Agenda Dynamics and Policy Subsystems. Journal of Politics, 53(4) 1044-74.

Baumgartner, Frank and Bryan Jones. 1993. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago.

Congress of the Philippines. 1990. Transcript: House of Representatives Committee Hearings on The Foreign Investment Act of 1991 (Committee on Trade and Industry, Committee on Economic Affairs and Committee on Labor and Employment).

Congress of the Philippines. 1990. Transcript: House of Representatives Session Proceedings on The Foreign Investment Act of 1991.

Congress of the Philippines. 1990. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on The Foreign Investment Act of 1991 (Committee on Economic Affairs).

Congress of the Philippines. 1990. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings The Foreign Investment Act of 1991.

Congress of the Philippines. 1991. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 1678 and House Bill 32496.

Congress of the Philippines. 1993. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1994 (Committee on Ways and Means).

Congress of the Philippines. 1994. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 357 and House Bill 14177.

Congress of the Philippines. 1994. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1994.

Congress of the Philippines. 1995. Transcript: House of Representatives Committee Hearings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991 (Committee on Trade and Industry and Committee on Economic Affairs).

Congress of the Philippines. 1995. Transcript: House Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991.

Congress of the Philippines. 1996. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 1399 and House Bill 5029.

Congress of the Philippines. 1996. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991 (Committee on Economic Affairs).

Congress of the Philippines. 1996. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings on the Amendments to The Foreign Investment Act of 1991.

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1998 (Committee on Ways and Means).

Congress of the Philippines. 1998. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1998.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on the Disagreeing Provisions of Senate Bill 763 and House Bill 7612.

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript: House of Representatives Committee Hearings on The Anti-Dumping Act of 1998 (Committee on Ways and Means and Committee on Trade and Industry).

Congress of the Philippines. 1999. Transcript: Senate Special Session.

Congress of the Philippines. 2001. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1745 and House Bill 3083.

Congress of the Philippines. 2001. Transcript: House of Representatives Committee Hearings on Money Laundering (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries).

Congress of the Philippines. 2001. Transcript: House of Representatives Session Proceedings on Money Laundering.

Congress of the Philippines. 2001. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on Money Laundering (Committee on Banks and Financial Institutions and Committee on Justice and Human Rights).

Congress of the Philippines. 2001. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings on Money Laundering.
           
Congress of the Philippines. 2002. Transcript: House of Representatives Committee Hearings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries, Committee on Economic Affairs and Committee on Justice).

Congress of the Philippines. 2002. Transcript: Senate Committee Hearings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act (Committee on Banks and Financial Institutions and Committee on Constitutional Amendments).

Congress of the Philippines. 2002. Transcript: Senate Session Proceedings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act.

Congress of the Philippines. 2003. Transcript: Bicameral Conference Committee on Senate Bill 2419 and House Bill 5655.

Congress of the Philippines. 2003. Transcript: House of Representatives Session Proceedings on the Amendments to the Anti-Money Laundering Act.

De Dios, Emmanuel and Paul Hutchcroft. 2003. Political Economy. In Balisacan, A. and Hill, H. (eds.), The Philippine Economy: Development, Policies, and Challenges. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.
FATF-GAFI. 2000. Review to Identify Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories: Increasing the Worldwide Effectiveness of the Anti-Money Laundering Measures. Paris: FATF/OECD.

FATF-GAFI. 2001. Review to Identify Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories: Increasing the Worldwide Effectiveness of the Anti-Money Laundering Measures. Paris: FATF/OECD.

FATF-GAFI. 2002. Review to Identify Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories: Increasing the Worldwide Effectiveness of the Anti-Money Laundering Measures. Paris: FATF/OECD.

FATF-GAFI. 2003. FATF Withdraws Countermeasures with Respect to Ukraine and Decides on Date for Countermeasures to the Philippines. Paris: FATF/OECD.
Hall, Peter. 1993. Policy Paradigms, Social Learnings and the State: The Case of Economic Policy-making in Britain. Comparative Politics, 25(3) 275-296.

Heclo, Hugh. 1974. Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden: From Relief to Income Maintenance. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Hogwood, Brian and Lewis Gunn. 1984. Policy Analysis for the Real World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Howlett, Michael and M Ramesh. 1995. Studying Public Policy: Policy Cycles and Policy Subsystems. New York: Oxford University Press.

Kingdon, John. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. Boston: Little Brown.

May, Peter. 1992. Policy Learning and Failure. Journal of Public Policy 12(4) 331-354.

Mendoza Jr., Amado. 2005. Politics of Tax Policy Making in the Philippines: The Comprehensive Tax Reform Program (CTRP) of President Ramos. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of the Philippines Diliman.

Pedro, Antonio. 2002. Legislating Banking Liberalization in the Philippines: Business-Government Relations in Policy Reform. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization: Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco Center/DLSU.

Peters, B. Guy. 1986. American Public Policy: Promise and Performance. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers, Inc.

Rebullida, Ma. Lourdes. 2003. The Politics of Urban Poor Housing: State and Civil Society Dynamics. Philippine Political Science Journal, 24(47) 37-68.

Rist, Ray. 1994. The Preconditions for Learning: Lessons from the Public Sector. In F.L. Leeuw, R.C. Rist and R.C. Sonnischen (eds.), Can Governments Learn: Comparative Perspectives on Evaluation and Organizational Learning. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

Tigno, Jorge. 2004. Governance and Public Policy in the Philippines: RA 8042 and the Deregulation of the Overseas Employment Sector. Philippine Political Science Journal, 25(48) 1-24.

Sabatier, Paul. 1987. Knowledge, Policy-Oriented Learning, and Policy Change: An Advocacy Coalition Framework. Knowledge: Creation, Diffusion, Utilization, 3(June) 649-692.

Sabatier, Paul. 1988. An Advocacy Coalition Framework of Policy Change and the Role of Policy-Oriented Learning Therein. Policy Sciences, 21(3-4) 129-168.

Sabatier, Paul and Hank Jenkins-Smith 1999. The Advocacy Coalition Framework: An Assessment. In Paul Sabatier (ed.), Theories of the Policy Process. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Schlesinger Jr., Arthur. 1986. The Cycle of American History. Boston: Houghton Mifflen.

Smith, Kevin and Christopher Larimer. 2009. The Public Policy Theory Primer. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Stewart, Joseph, David Hedge and James Lester. 2008. Public Policy: An Evolutionary Approach. Boston: Thomson Wadsworth.




[1] The author is Assistant Professor at the Department of Social Sciences, University of the Philippines Los Baños and is pursuing the PhD in Development Studies (by Research) at De La Salle University. 
[2] Refers to Brillo 2010a
[3] Refers to Brillo 2012a
[4] The paucity of scholarly works on policy modification is largely a consequence of being subsumed to the broader literature of policy change, where policy shift (substantive alteration or replacement of the prevailing policy) is given preference over policy modification (rectification or adjustment of the existing policy).

[5] Entitled “Foreign Investments Without Incentives,” specifically Article 44 to 56.
[6] Malaysia captured $12.8billion or 50.5%; Thailand received $5.7billion or 22.6%; and Indonesia got $5.2billion or 20.7%.
[7] The Senate version is for the retention while the House version is for the removal.

A Theoretical Review on Philippine Policy Making: The Weak State-Elitist Framework and the Pluralist Perspective

Bing Baltazar C. Brillo[1][2]
           
2012 Philippine Quarterly of Culture and Society, vol. 39, no. 1, pp. 54-76.

 Abstract

The article is a theoretical review of the studies made by scholars in policy making in the Philippines. It begins with a discussion on the centrality of the concept of elite in analyzing policy making and its link to particularistic policies. The elite concept is then associated to the weak state conceptualization, where the rise of predatory elite ramifies into state weakness; specifically, the decline in the government’s capacity to produce public regarding policies. Political dynamics are explained in terms a zero-sum relationship, as the decrease in government’s capacity in policy making is generally rationalized in terms of the elite-captured state or the foreign-dominated state. Afterwards, the article elucidates the limitations of the weak state-elitist framework, particularly in the light of the changing nature of the politics in Philippine policy making. It closes with a discourse on the pluralist perspective and its challenge over dominance of the weak state-elitist perspective.


The Elite Conceptualization and Philippine Policy Making

Over the years, scholars have examined the intricacies of policy making in the Philippines. The scholarships mostly showed preference for the elitist perspective in analyzing the politics behind the policies. Political power in Philippine society is presumed to be skewed and concentrated in one dominant group, and that this elite controls policy making most of the time. Among the early scholarship under this genre was the work of Carl Lande using the patron-client framework to explain the incoherence of policies (see also Lande 1958; Lynch 1959; Hollnsteiner 1963). Lande (1965: 1) observed that “the Philippine polity, unlike those of most present-day Western democracies, is structured less by organized interest groups or by individuals who in politics think of themselves as members of categories, i.e. of distinctive social classes or occupations, than by a network of mutual aid relationships between pairs of individuals.” These dyadic relationships involve exchanges between the prosperous patrons and their poor and dependent clients. The political elite that controls the government and its policy making apparatus largely comes from those who can afford to be patron, that is those who have the wealth and the position to do favors for large numbers of ordinary people. These have profound consequences on policies, as the heavy reliance on vertical and horizontal dyadic relationships steers policy making towards the pursuit of providing rewards (e.g., special privileges, monopolies, or unwarranted exemptions), while offering little incentives to pursue categorical programs. The legislative program becomes more of a personal rather than ideological or party-based program. As the overarching intention is to satisfy clientele demands, policy making becomes continually marred by accommodations and concessions which lead to inconsistent or aimless policies.

Some scholars modified the patron-client framework by adopting the political machine perspective, where material rewards rather than personal ties are the center of analysis. James Scott (1969; 1972) declared that the traditional patron-client relation based on loyalty and deference is being transformed into a political machine (see also Nowak and Snyder 1970; Wolters 1984; Magno A. 1988; Magno F. 1989; Gutierrez 1994). Other scholars focused on conflict and coercion rather than symbiotic personal ties. For instance, Benedict Kerkvliet (1977; 1995) concluded that the amiable dyadic model is deficient in explaining the uncongenial and antagonistic relationships that exist between people of unequal status and class positions as well as marginalized the importance of values, ideas, organizations and conflicts. While John Sidel (1989) asserted that the patron-client framework fails to adequately account for the change and continuity in Philippine rural politics as well as the role of coercion and the autonomy of localities from central control. Although the means have changed, from personal ties to material rewards or coercion, the implication on policy making is the same— the political elite controls policy making and outcome to secure political relevance and continuity.

Other scholars used the dependency or neocolonial framework in rationalizing foreign influence in policy making and outcome.[3] Devotees echoed that the Philippine polity must be seen in view of the persistence of foreign influence and control over the government (see Constantino 1970; Lichauco 1973; Bello and Rivera 1977). The fundamental premise assumes that the “American-given” Philippine independence in 1946 did not totally free country from foreign domination; instead, neocolonialism particularly in the economy was instituted (Constantino 1970; Lichauco 1973; Stauffer 1973; Shalom 1981). By implication, the status of Filipino political elite in shaping policies was upheld but downgraded to an accomplice of foreign interest (especially American interest), as major policies are deemed dictated from the outside. This interpretation presupposes a subservient domestic elite and a policy making manipulated by external powers.

With the redemocratization after the fall of Marcos regime, the appeal of the other frameworks faded. [4] Scholars began to embrace the elite democracy framework and its variants which quickly became the dominant perspective in depicting Philippine politics. The strength of the perspective is its inclusiveness; compared to the patron-client framework, it takes into consideration more variables (such as corruption, fraud, coercion and violence), and compared to the dependency framework, it acknowledges that foreign interests at times infringes on Philippine sovereignty but it does not suggest an exaggerated view (Kerkvliet 1995; Quimpo 2005). Beginning with what is generally considered the pioneering work, Dante Simbulan (1965) studying the socio-economic elites, contended that Philippine politics revolves around the elite families. These elites, which profoundly benefited during the Spanish and American colonial period, are resilient. As these families continue to hold political (and economic) power, they, in effect, continuously monopolize policy making over the years. Simbulan’s thesis was echoed by Benedict Anderson (1988) in Cacique Democracy, as he presented an elaborate discussion on the continuity of the elite families from the Spanish caciquism to the American electoralism and to the present. In particular, Anderson noted that the transformation of the caciques to political dynasties occurred during the American colonial period when they secured the newly created elective offices and filled the bureaucracy with their relatives and supporters, and that this so-called “cacique democracy” continued and reached its heyday in 1954 to 1972. He further asserted that after the Marcos dictatorship cacique democracy was restored. The traditional families again dominated the electoral-political arena and by implication the governmental decision making. And Alfred McCoy (1993: 10), focusing more on contemporary Philippine politics, concluded that one of the key elements to have contributed directly to the formation of powerful political families is “the rise of “rents” as a significant share of the nation’s economy.”[5] Here, McCoy’s is suggesting that the policy decisions made in the past, specifically policies intentionally enacted to benefit the elite families, have built up, transformed and reinforced them. In general, the Simbulan-Anderson-McCoy’s observations on political elites are shared by many scholars who believe that the post-EDSA politics was a reversion to the pre-Martial Law elite democracy where political elites conveniently used elections as a relatively peaceful way of competing and alternating political power among themselves (see Hawes 1987; Bello and Gershman 1990; Stauffer 1990; Timberman 1991; Caoili 1993; Rocamora 1998; Teehankee 2001; Thompson 2010).

Other studies under the elite democracy genre specifically focused on the relationship with elite rule, particularistic policies, and development. For instance, Paul Hutchcroft (1991) contended that the powerful and conservative elites who enjoy autonomy from the state have resisted change. Using the concept of a patrimonial state, where the political administration is treated as a personal affair, he argued that the Philippine government is continually choked by particularistic demands and actions coming from and on behalf of oligarchs and cronies. Likewise, Olivia Caoili (1993, 2006a, 2006b), focusing on the Philippine Congress, pointed out that having a legislature traditionally dominated by exclusivistic political elite has a profound effect on substantive policy making, as lawmakers tend to be more preoccupied with local bills or particularistic legislation. In a similar vein, Shiela Coronel et al. (2004; viii), in examining the character of the contemporary Congress, admitted the existence of some changes in the elite-dominated Congress (such as the entry of professionals, celebrities, media people, individuals from the middle class, and incorporation of the party-list representatives), but, she stressed that the legislature continues to be “an elite body that defends the interests of the wealthy and the powerful while occasionally being open to demands from below.” These studies demonstrated the adverse effect of the longevity of elite rule, as elite families tend to use political power to benefit themselves and their supporters. In policy making, this practice translates to particularistic policies that cater to private interests rather than collective good. As aptly resonated by the Institute for Popular Democracy (IPD): “the continued control of these families over politics and wealth is one of the most formidable structural obstacles to democratization” and development (Gutierrez 1994: 302).

The more recent alternative perspective— the contested democracy framework— although it incorporates the actions of forces below (e.g., ordinary individuals, subordinate class, marginalized communities), it still continues to acknowledge the ascendancy of the elites in policy making (see Wurfel 1988; Kerkvliet 1995; Franco 2001; Quimpo 2005). “The oligarchs, caciques, bosses, and trapos are still very dominant in Philippine politics, but their predatory rule has been challenged and continues to be challenged by the poor and marginalized” (Quimpo 2005: 243). For example, Jose Magadia (2003), illustrating the unevenness and inconsistencies in societal participation in policy making, surveyed three major social policies of the Aquino administration—agrarian reform, labor relations reform, and urban reform policies. Although the elitist Congress still determines national policies, he argued that the higher the level of political catalysis (the process of accelerating state-society interaction where state and society actors send a signal of willingness to engage each other), the greater the participation of societal organizations in policy deliberations. More recently, Teresa Tadem (2009), discussing the contemporary technocratic-elite control over decision-making on economic policy, noted the continual challenge presented by civil society and social movement. As in the formulation of the Philippine government position in the World Trade Organization (WTO)-Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), she observed that the experience reflects the emergence of “reformist” technocrats who are open to negotiating with civil society actors in formulating policies. These studies suggest that, to some extent, the forces below are moderating the elite influence on substantive policy making.

Despite the variations among the frameworks, overall, one common element shared by them is— the centrality of the concept of the elite in Philippine policy making. Patron-client involves a reciprocal relationship between elites (patrons) and dependent clients; dependency comprises of the collaboration between the domestic elites and imperialist elites; contested democracy includes the challenge posed by the poor and marginalized against an elite dominated government; and elite democracy which fundamentally consists of the dominance, alliances, and rivalry among the elites (see Table 1). This encompassing utilization of the concept of elites parallels the inclination of scholars towards a weak conception of the state, as political dynamics are generally explained in terms of the correlation between a powerful elite and a weak state. The weak state-elitist explanation is anchored on a zero-sum relationship, where the rise of the predatory elite results in the decline of government power, and thus, diminishing the capacity to produce public regarding policies.

Table 1: The Centrality of the Concept of the Elite in Philippine Polity
Political Frameworks            Depicting the “Elite”

Patron-client                            the reciprocal relationship between elites (patrons) and dependent clients

Dependency                            the collaboration between the domestic elites and imperialist elites

Elite democracy                      the dominance, alliances, and rivalry among the elites

Contested democracy             the challenge posed by the poor and marginalized against an elite dominated government


The Philippine Weak State: the Elite-Captured State and the Foreign-Dominated State

The Philippine history is characterized by powerful political oligarchies and a weak state (McCoy 1993). The weak state-predatory elite explanation of society is encased in the broader weak state-strong society framework and is grounded on two key variables: the centrality powerful Filipino families (for pioneering studies, see Fox 1959; Grossholtz 1964; Simbulan 1965; Agpalo 1972; Green 1973) and a weak Philippine state. The weak state-strong society framework was popularized by Joel Migdal (1988), as he argued that third world states weakness can be traced to powerful social forces (commonly the dominance of elite clans) that continue to compete with the government for authority. This makes the government ineffective in carrying out development-oriented policies and programs. Following this logic, the Philippine weak state is more often than not acted upon rather than being an independent actor that can initiate and undertake reform; as important government actions, such as assignment of privileges, is largely determined by the personal discretion of the oligarchs controlling or holding official positions (Hutchcroft 1991; 1993; 1998).

The Philippine weak state conception has been extensively utilized by scholars. Temario Rivera (1991) depicted the Philippine state as captured by competing societal interests which enjoys little autonomy from dominant social classes and entrenched particularistic groups. Francisco Magno (1992) showed the inability of the Philippine state to enforce its rules, particularly on forest regulation policies. Patricio Abinales (1992) pointed out the role played by distance (spatial and demographic factors) in tipping the balance for societal actors and weakening the Philippine state. In another work, Abinales (1998: 158) opined that “the caciques prospered well under the weak state structures.” Felipe Miranda (1992) argued that the Philippine weak state is intertwined with a structurally strong and dominant Presidency. Jose Almonte (1993) described a weak state as unable to intervene and democratize the economy, particularly in wresting economic control from the Filipino oligarchs. Amado Doronila (1994) argued that decentralizing the authority and resources of the central government in favor of the local governments are creating mutually exclusive tensions that contribute significantly to the weakening of the state. Joel Rocamora (1998: 4) characterized the weakness of the state as the inability of the Philippine government “to formulate and implement a coherent economic development strategy or to develop political institutions capable of providing a reliable regulatory framework for the economy.” Hutchcroft (1998) portrayed the Philippine state as a patrimonial oligarchic state, which is preyed upon by an economically autonomous oligarchy that uses the government and its instrumentalities as the principal means to further accumulate wealth and entrench their position. Herman Joseph Kraft (2003) equated the growth and persistence of terrorism in the country as indicative of a weak Philippine state, as the government is unable to mobilize the requisite economic and political resources needed to address the multi-faceted challenges it currently is facing. Walden Bello et al. (2004: 4) argued that ”the American pattern of a weak central authority coexisting with a powerful upper-class social organization (“civil society” in today’s parlance) was reproduced in the Philippines, creating a weak state that was constantly captured by upperclass interests and preventing the emergence of the activist “developmental” state.” Patricio Abinales and Donna Amoroso (2005: 1) defined state weakness as “the persistent inability of the state to provide basic services, guarantee peace and order, and foster economic development” and “manifested in uncollected taxes and uncontrolled crime, bloated bureaucracies and denuded forests, low teacher salaries, and high emigration rates.” Abinales (2008), in his more recent work, observed that the resilience of Philippine Presidents can be attributed to another dimension of a weak state. Although state weakness is primarily the result of social forces expropriating state resources and programs to advance patrimonial interests, this attitude for plunder enables the Presidents to secure support from social forces and to "govern;" as Presidents craft mutually beneficial compromises with local political clans, strongmen and women, warlords and bosses and make state largesse available in exchange for fidelity to their authority. Ben Reid (2008) assessed that in a weak state dynamics where clientelism and semiclientilism predominate, even civil society which is supposed to be a conditioning force is ultimately absorbed by the clientelist relationships. And more recently, Alex Magno (2009) defined weak state as transactional, as it responds to particularistic political stimulus from specific constituencies, vulnerable to political accommodation, compromises the integrity of policies to suit immediate contingencies, and act on constituencies that are insistently noisy rather than ideas that are fundamentally sound. Overall, these discussions showed the overwhelming tendency among scholars of using the weak state-elitist framework as the preferred explanation for the “negativities” (e.g., economic debacle, bureaucratic weakness, impotency in enforcement, inability to intervene, persistence of terrorism, and occurrence of particularistic policies) in the Philippines (see Table 2).

Table 2: The Pervasiveness of the Weak State Thesis in Philippine Political Literature
        Scholars                                                              Utilization of the Concept    
The weak state concept is generally used as the preferred explanation for the many “negativities” in Philippine polity, such as:

economic debacle,
bureaucratic weakness,
impotency in enforcement,
inability to intervene,
persistence of terrorism,
and occurrence of particularistic     policies
 
Temario Rivera (1991)
Francisco Magno (1992)
Patricio Abinales (1992, 1998, and 2008)
Felipe Miranda (1992)
Jose Almonte (1993)
Amado Doronila (1994)
Joel Rocamora (1998)
Hutchcroft (1998)
Herman Joseph Kraft (2003)
Walden Bello et al. (2004)
Patricio Abinales and Donna Amoroso (2005)
Ben Reid (2008)
Alex Magno (2009)


Even in the few studies made in policy making, the trend continues to follow the weak state-elitist framework. In general, the studies contend that the legislative process is controlled and manipulated by coherent political elites, and as a consequence, policy outcomes reflect their vested interest. For instance, Paul Hutchcroft (who is considered to have made the most extensive studies under this genre), in examining the politics of preferential credit policy and banking policy respectively, maintained a state dominated by socioeconomic elites. Hutchcroft (1993) attributed the incoherence of the credit policy to the weak and patrimonial nature of the Philippine state, where policy is captured by special interests resulting to the abuse of public finances and the private banking sector. In his other work, Hutchcroft (1998) analyzing the effect of the relationship between the state and elite families in the banking sector concluded that because of rampant favoritism and weak state regulations, the oligarchs were able to plunder the banking sector by abusing their loan portfolios and engaging in cartel practices. This practice, he further asserted persists despite regime change. Moreover, Hutchcroft, applying the concept of booty capitalism, equated the domination of oligarchic clans to the unpredictability and inconsistency in banking policies and the dismal state of the Philippine economy. The archetypal example here is the well documented “abuse” of the Philippine National Bank by the oligarchic sugar bloc (Quirino 1974; McCoy 1988; Rivera 1994). In another study, Emmanuel De Dios (1990), analyzing the Philippine political economy, noted the conspicuous continuity in economic policy in the country despite the post-EDSA transition to democratic processes and institutions. The continuance of policy from preMartial Law to post-1986, he explained, was due to the persistence of the “old” political economy, where the economic and political elites dominated the state’s policy making. Rivera (1994: 20), examining the process of industrialization in the Philippines based on the development of the domestic sector from 1950 to 1986, observed that the persistence of protectionist policies is traceable to “the internal structuring and class formation of the ISI (import-substitution industrialization) bourgeoisie— its linkages with the export-landlord class, with foreign capital, and with the state apparatus.” He concluded that the failure of Philippine industrialization was caused by three interlinked factors: first, the control of the landed families over the manufacturing sector; second, the alliance between the landed families and foreign investors; and lastly, a weak state lacking autonomy. While Caoili (1993 and 2006b), examining the post1987 Philippine legislature, observed that the homogeneity of the political elites resulted in the persistent conservatism of Congress and the neglect of basic issues affecting national development.

In addressing the weak state problem in policy making, scholars usually offer a standard prescription— the insulation of the government from the subversion of vested interests. For example, Manuel Montes (1992) concluded that strengthening the state means building its capacity to make economic intervention independent of particularistic interest, where the government is capable of formulating and implementing economic policy with sufficient autonomy from these interests. Rivera (1994) argued that only through a strong, autonomously embedded state can the government break the continuing power of the elites, lead a social coalition for industrial growth, and produce economic policies that could creatively respond to opportunities in the world market. Doronila (1994) maintained that despite the tensions caused by devolution and localism, there is a need to build a strong Philippine state to facilitate and promote reform. Similarly, Almonte (2007: 119) stressed that “our most urgent need is to raise the political capacity of the Philippine State— to set it free from the dominance of vested interest groups and enable it to act— unequivocably— on behalf of the common good and the national interest.” Here, political capacity refers to the legitimacy and effectiveness of state institutions, and insuring the autonomy of these administrative elite, that is insulating it from the importuning of particularistic groups. 

Furthermore, other scholars such as Constantino (1970), Lichauco (1973), and Bello and Rivera (1977), early on, focused on another dimension of the weak state conception vis-à-vis policy making. [6] These scholars associated state weakness to the susceptibility of government to interference from external actors, such as foreign governments, international organizations or transnational businesses, in making substantive policy decisions. This is similar to the dependency framework’s thesis, their conception associates external influence in bringing about particularistic policies, as foreign interests are considered taking precedence in policy outcomes. Thus, under this circumstance, the government’s capacity to legislate public-regarding policies is significantly impaired.

            Table 3: The Weak State-Elitist Tradition and Policy Making in the Philippines
                 Scholars                                      Rationalization for Incapacity in
         Legislating Public-Regarding Policy

Hutchcroft (1993)                                          
            Hutchcroft (1998)                                          
Quirino (1974)                                               
McCoy (1988)                                                
Rivera (1994)                                                 
            Gutierrez (1994)                                              elite-captured state
De Dios (1990)                                              
Montes (1992)                                                
Doronila (1994)                                              
Almonte (2007)                                              
Caoili (1993 and 2006b)                                                                
Constantino (1970)                                        
Lichauco (1973)                                              foreign-dominated state
Bello and Rivera (1977)                                 
                                                                       
In general, the weak state-elitist literature suggests that the Philippine polity’s persistent incapacity in legislating public-regarding policy is associated with two conditions of the state: first, an elite-captured state where coherent political elites continuously control policy making; and second, a foreign-dominated state where the enduring external influence shapes policy formulation and decision (see Table 3).

The Pluralist Perspective and Philippine Policy Making

In contemporary political thought, there are two dominant perspectives in interpreting politics (i.e. the process in making political decisions)— the “pluralists” and the “elitists” perspectives. The pluralist perspective views the government as an arena among competing interests in society and that policies are political decisions that reflect the acceptable equilibrium among contending groups (see Truman 1951; Bentley 1967; Dahl 1961, 1967 and 1971; Lindblom 1977). This perspective put emphasis on diversity and competition among political actors, as they utilize power and resources (e.g., money, supporters, expertise, information, or connections) to influence government’s policy decisions. On the other hand, the elitist perspective views the government as the key entity used by the dominant group in a stratified society (i.e. the haves and the have-nots) to advance their interests; hence, policies are deemed as political decisions intended to serve their vested interest (see Pareto 1935; Mosca 1939; Mills 1956; Michels 1962). This perspective accentuates the collaboration among the elites in controlling the government and its policy decisions.

With the ascendancy of the weak state-elitist framework, scholars have shown preference for the elitist perspective in interpreting Philippine politics. Political power in society is presumed to be skewed and concentrated in a privileged group rather than spread across groups, and that this coherent political elite controls policy making most of the time. This conventional conception, however, needs validation. Particularly, in light of the few empirical studies in Philippine policy making showing, that instead of a tight-knit political elites conspiring, there is increasing diversity and competition among political elites. For instance, Rigoberto Tiglao (1992), in explaining the politics of policy making during the Aquino administration, contended that the elite fragmentation after the democratic restoration has led to intense competition for political control. As a consequence, this propelled the government towards policies that satisfy short-term populist demands rather than long-term development-oriented policies. Antonio Pedro (2002), studying the legislation for the liberalization of foreign banking, focused on the existing nature of state-society and business-government relationships. He asserted that Huchcroft’s booty capitalism framework is incomplete, since it failed to note the changing dynamics in policy making. He concluded that the various actors in government, business, and civil society have acted autonomously in the legislation of the law. In a similar vein, Eric Batalla (2002), analyzing the politics financial liberalization in the Philippines, offered insights on the nature of state, business-government relations, and policy making. He agreed with Pedro’s findings that the characteristics of policy making as well as the government-business relations in the Philippines is changing. He further contended that the fragmentation among the political and business elites has made it possible for the government to act autonomously and succeed in making policy change or reform.

More recently, Brillo (2010), analyzing the legislation and re-legislation of the anti-dumping law, touched on the interagency competition among the governmental actors. He observed that executive agencies saw the repeal process as an opportunity to expand their domain and scope of authority. The issue of jurisdiction in R.A. 7843 led to a bureaucratic battle between government agencies (i.e. Department of Finance [DOF] vs. Department of Trade and Industry [DTI]) which spilled over to Congress, with the House of Representatives backing DOF and the Senate supporting DTI. In another study, Brillo (2012a), examining the legislation of the foreign investment law, analyzed the bureaucrat-politician’s dynamics in its policy making. He argued that contrary to the weak state thesis a different set of dynamics exist between the bureaucrats and politicians. He noted that the bureaucrats were active, autonomous, and dominant in policy making, as they basically determined the inputs of the discussions, the critical content of the proposal, and most importantly, the policy outcome. On the other hand, the politicians were passive and reactive in the lawmaking process, as they deferred to the wisdom of bureaucrats and their participation was largely confined to fine tuning— adjustments or refinements in the form of stipulations or exceptions to suit and placate supporters, constituents, allies or favored interests. In the same light, Brillo (2012b), re-examining the politics of the policy making of the foreign bank liberalization law in the Philippines, made a fine-grained assessment of the quality of pluralism that existed among actors in the legislation of the banking policy. He contended that the law took a conservative form since the Senate has a formidable alliance with the bureaucracy and interest groups (i.e. The Senate-Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas[BSP],Bankers Association of the Philippines[BAP], resident foreign banks bloc), as compared to the House of Representatives, and that the internal dynamics between the Senate and the House of Representatives made it difficult for the former to make concession while easier for the latter to make compromises. Summing up, these studies suggest that contemporary policy making is better viewed from the standpoint of pluralism— a political process where a range of autonomous actors competes in influencing and defining the policy outcome (Self 1985; Smith 1990; Howlett and Ramesh 1995).

Concluding Remarks

In Philippine literature, the dynamics in Philippine polity, specifically, the government’s capacity in legislating policies has been, time and again, interpreted by scholars using the dominant weak state-elitist framework. In general, the weak state-elitist framework presupposes that the Philippine polity’s chronic incapacity of producing public-regarding policies is deemed the consequence of two conditions of the state. First, the elite-captured state which refers to the enduring control of powerful, homogenous political elites over the government’s policy making mechanism. And second, the foreign-dominated state which refers to the vulnerability of the government’s policy decisions to external influences or interferences. In both cases— whether by virtue of the elite-captured state or the foreign-dominated state— there is an adverse effect since the governmental capacity in legislating public-regarding policies is considerably compromised.

A small voice among scholars has questioned the soundness and adequacy of the weak state-elitist framework. They have pointed out that its clichéd explanation is out of sync with the contemporary policy making experiences. By implication, the weak state-elitist view is deemed overuse and, by taking a broad perspective, is too general to be of much analytical use in policy making analysis (Atkinson and Coleman 1989; Howlett and Ramesh 1995; Mikamo 1997). These scholars suggested that pluralism better characterizes present-day Philippine policy making since there is increasing fragmentation among political actors in legislating policies. Here, the actors are seen as autonomous with distinct interests, resources, and power which give rise to divergent positions across policy issues over time. Thus, in the light of the changing nature of policy making in the Philippines, these studies imply the need to reassess the dominant weak state-elitist framework.


References

Abinales, Patricio. 1992. Mindanao in the Politics of the Philippine Nation-State: A Brief Sketch. Philippine Political Science Journal, 1991-1992(33-36) 120-141.

Abinales, Patricio. 1998. Images of State Power: Essays on Philippine Politics from the Margins. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Press.

Abinales, Patricio. 2008. The Philippines: Weak State, Resilient President. Southeast Asian Affairs, 293-312, http://muse.jhu.edu/journals/southeast_asian_affairs/v2008/2008.abinales.html

Abinales, Patricio and Donna Amoroso. 2005. State and Society in the Philippines. Pasig City: Anvil Publishing, Inc.

Agpalo, Remegio. 1972. The Political Elite and the People: A Study of Politics in Occidental Mindoro. Manila: College of Public Administration, University of the Philippines.

Almonte, Jose. 1993. The Politics of Development in the Philippines. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 9(2) 107-116.

Almonte, Jose. 2007. To Put Our House in Order: We Must Level the Playing Field. Manila: Foundation for Economic Freedom, Inc.

Anderson, Benedict. 1988. Cacique Democracy in the Philippines: Origins and Dreams. New Left Review, 169(May-June) 3-31.

Atkinson, Michael and William Coleman. 1989. Strong States and Weak States: Sectoral Policy Networks in Advanced Capitalist Economies. British Journal of Political Science, 19(1) 47-67.

Batalla, Eric. 2002. The Politics of Financial Liberalization. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization: Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco Center/DLSU.

Bello, Walden and John Gershman. 1990. Democratization and Stabilization in the Philippines. Critical Sociology, 17(1) 35-56.

Bello, Walden and Severina Rivera. 1977. Logistics of Repression and Other Essays. Washington, DC: Friends of the Filipino People.

Bello, Walden, Herbert Docena, Marissa de Guzman and Mary Lou Malig. 2004. The Anti-Development State: The Political Economy of Permanent Crisis in the Philippines. Pasig City: Anvil Publishing, Inc.

Bentley, Arthur. 1967. The Process of Government. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2010. The Politics of the Anti-Dumping Law of the Philippines. UPLB Journal , 8(1) 17-29.

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2012a. Bureaucrats and Politicians in Policy Making: The Case of the Foreign Investment Act of the Philippines (still unpublished).

Brillo, Bing Baltazar. 2012b. Assessing the Pluralism in Philippine Polity: The Policy Making of the Foreign Bank Liberalization Act (still unpublished).

Caoili, Olivia. 1993. The Philippine Congress: Executive- Legislative Relations and the Restoration of Democracy. Quezon City: UP-CIDS and UP Press.

Caoili, Olivia. 2006a. The Philippine Legislature: From Pre-Spanish Times to the Eve of Martial Law. In Noel Morada and Teresa Tadem (eds.), Philippine Politics and Governance. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Diliman.

Caoili, Olivia. 2006b. The Restored Philippine Congress. In Noel Morada and Teresa Tadem (eds.), Philippine Politics and Governance. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Diliman.

Constantino, Renato. 1970. Dissent and Counter-Consciousness. Quezon City: Malaya Books.

Coronel, Shiela, Yvonne Chua, Luz Rimban and Boomba Cruz. 2004. The Rulemakers: How the Wealth and Well-Born Dominate Congress. Quezon City: PCIJ.

Dahl, Robert. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy in an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Dahl, Robert. 1967. Pluralist Democracy in the United States. Chicago: Rand McNally.

Dahl, Robert. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

De Dios, Emmanuel. 1990. A Political Economy of Philippine Policy-Making. In John W. Langford and K. Lorne Brownsey (eds.), Economic Policy-Making in the Asia-Pacific Region. Halifax, Nova Scotia: Institute for Research on Public Policy.

Doronila, Amando. 1994. Reflections on a Weak State and Dilemma of Decentralization
Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 10(1) 48-54.

Fox, Robert. 1959. The Study of Filipino Society and its Significance to Programs of Economic and Social Development. Philippine Sociological Review, 7(1-2) 6.

Franco, Jennifer. 2001. Elections and Democratization in the Philippines. New York: Routledge.

Green, Justin. 1973. Social Backgrounds, Attitudes and Political Behavior: A Study of a Philippine Elite. Southeast Asia: An International Quarterly, 2(3) 301-338.

Grossholtz, Jean. 1964. Politics in the Philippines. Boston: Little Brown.

Gutierrez, Eric. 1994. The Ties that Bind: A Guide to Family, Business and Other Interests in the Ninth House of Representatives. Pasig: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism.

Hawes, Gary. 1987. The Philippine State and the Marcos Regime: The Politics of Export. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Hollnsteiner, Mary. 1963. Dynamics of Power in a Philippine Municipality. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Community Development Research Council.

Howlett, Michael and M Ramesh. 1995. Studying Public Policy: Policy Cycles and Policy Subsystems. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hutchcroft, Paul. 1991. Oligarchs and Cronies in the Philippine State: The Politics of Patrimonial Plunder. World Politics, 43(3) 414-450.

Hutchcroft, Paul. 1993. Selective Squander: The Politics of Preferential Credit Allocation in the Philippines. In Stephan Haggard, Chung H. Lee, and Sylvia Maxfield (eds.), The Politics of Finance in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Hutchcroft, Paul. 1998. Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Ithaca: Cornel University Press.

Kerkvliet,  Benedict. 1977. The Huk Rebellion: A Study of Peasant Revolt in the Philippines. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Kerkvliet, Benedict. 1995. Toward a More Comprehensive Analysis of Philippine Politics: Beyond the Patron-Client, Factional Framework. Journal of Southeast Asian Studies, 26(2) 401-419.

Kraft, Herman Joseph. 2003. The Philippines: The Weak State and the Global War on Terror. Kasarinlan: the Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 18(1-2) 133-152.

Lande, Carl. 1958. Politics in the Philippines. Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University.

Lande, Carl. 1965. Leaders, Factions and Parties: The Structure of Philippine Politics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Southeast Asian Studies.

Lichauco, Alejandro. 1973. The Lichauco Paper: Imperialism in the Philippines. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Lindblom, Charles. 1977. Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.

Lynch, Frank, S.J. 1959. Social Class in a Bikol Town. In Research Series no. 1, Philippine Studies Program, Department of Anthropology. Chicago: University of Chicago.

Magadia, Jose. 2003. State-Society Dynamics: Policy Making in a Restored Democracy. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.

Magno, Alexander. 1988. The Declining Clans. Kasarinlan: the Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 3(3) 72.

Magno, Alexander. 2009. Weak State. First Person, The Philippine Star, October 8, 1. http://www.philstar.com/Article.aspx?articleid=512148

Magno, Francisco. 1989. State Patronage and Local Elites. Kasarinlan: the Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 4(3) 5-12.

Magno, Francisco. 1992. Weak State, Ravage Forests: Political Constraints to Sustainable Upland Management in the Philippines. Philippine Political Science Journal, 1991-1992(33-36) 79-96.

McCoy, Alfred. 1988. Quezon’s Commonwealth: The Emergence of Philippine Authoritarianism. In Ruby Paredes (ed.), Philippine Colonial Democracy. New Haven: Yale Center for International and Area Studies.

McCoy, Alfred. 1993. An Anarchy of Families: State and Family in the Philippines. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Michels, Roberto. 1962. Political Parties. New York: Free Press.

Migdal, Joel. 1988. Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Mikamo, Shingo. 1997. Economic Policy-Making in the Philippines. UP-CIDS Chronicle, 2(3-4) 64-72.

Mills, C. Wright. 1956. The Power Elite. New York: Oxford University Press.

Miranda, Felipe. 1992. Leadership and Political Stabilization in a Post-Aquino Philippines. Philippine Political Science Journal, 1991-1992(33-36) 142-222.

Montes, Manuel. 1992. The Politics of Liberalization: The Aquino Government’s 1990 Tariff Reform Initiative. In David Timberman (ed.), The Politics of Economic Reform in Southeast Asia. Makati: Asian Institute of Management.

Mosca, Gaetano. 1939. The Ruling Class. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Nowak, Thomas and Kay Snyder. 1970. Urbanization and Clientelist Systems in the Philippines. Philippine Journal of Public Administration, 14(3) 261-262.

Pareto, Vilfredo. 1935. The Mind and Society. London: Cape.

Pedro, Antonio. 2002. Legislating Banking Liberalization in the Philippines: Business-Government Relations in Policy Reform. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization: Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco Center/DLSU.

Quimpo, Nathan Gilbert. 2005. Oligarchic Patrimonialism, Bossism, Electoral Clientelism, and Contested Democracy in the Philippines. Comparative Politics, 37(2) 229-250. http://www.jstor.org/pss/20072884

Quirino, Carlos. 1974. History of the Philippine Sugar Industry. Manila: Kalayaan Publishing.

Reid, Ben. 2008. Development NGOs, Semiclientelism, and the State in the Philippines: From “Crossover” to Double-crossed. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 23(1) 4-42.

Rivera, Temario. 1991. Class, the State and Foreign Capital: The Politics of Philippine Industrialization, 1950-1986. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin.

Rivera, Temario. 1994. The State and Industrial Transformation: Comparative and Local Insights. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 10(1) 55-80.

Rocamora, Joel. 1998. Philippine Political Parties: Continuity and Change. Quezon City: Institute for Popular Democracy.

Scott, James. 1969. Corruption, Machine Politics, and Political Change. American Political Science Review, 63(4) 1142-1158.

Scott, James. 1972. The Erosion of Patron-Client and Social Change in Southeast Asia. Journal of Asian Studies, 32(1) 5-37.

Self, Peter. 1985. Political Theories of Modern Government: Its Role and Reform. London: Allen and Unwin.

Shalom, Stephen. 1981. The United States and the Philippines: A Study of Neocolonialism. Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues.

Sidel, John. 1989. Beyond Patron-Client Relation: Warlordism and Local Politics in the Philippines. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 4(3) 19-30.

Simbulan, Dante. 1965. A Study of the Socio-economic Elite in Philippine Politics and Government, 1946-1963. Ph.D. dissertation, Australian National University.

Smith, Martin. 1990. Pluralism, Reformed Pluralism and Neopluralism: The Role of Pressure Groups in Policy-Making. Political Studies, 38( ) 303-304.

Stauffer, Robert. 1973. The Marcos Coup in the Philippines. Monthly Review, 24(4) 19-27.

Stauffer, Robert. 1990. Philippine Democracy: Contradictions of the Third World Redemocratization. Kasarinlan, Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 6(1-2) 7-22.

Tadem, Teresa. 2009. “Popularizing” Technocratic Decision-Making: The Formulation of the Philippine Negotiating Position in the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 24(1) 35-60.

Teehankee, Julio. 2001. Emerging Dynasties in the Post-Marcos House of Representatives. Philippine Political Science Journal, 22(45) 55-78.

Thompson, Mark. 2010. After Populism: Winning the ‘War’ for Bourgeois Democracy in the Philippines. In Yuko Kasuya and Nathan Gilbert Quimpo (eds.), The Politics of Change in the Philippines. Pasig City: Anvil Publishing, Inc.

Tiglao, Rigoberto. 1992. The Dilemmas of Economic Policymaking in a “People Power” State. In David Timberman (ed.), The Politics of Economic Reform in Southeast Asia. Makati: Asian Institute of Management.

Timberman, David. 1991. A Changeless Land: Continuity and Change in Philippine Politics. New York: M.E. Sharpe.

Truman, David. 1951. The Governmental Process. New York: Knoft.

Wolters, Willem. 1984. Politics, Patronage and Class Conflict in Central Luzon. Quezon City: New Day Publishers.

Wurfel, David. 1988. Filipino Politics: Development and Decay. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.




[2] The author is an Assistant Professor at the Department of Social Sciences, University of the Philippines Los Baños. 
[3] The ascendancy of this neocolonial interpretation of Philippine politics was aided by the global rediscovery of imperialism and the rise of dependency school, as well as the heavy reliance of the Marcos government on economic and military assistance from the United States (Quimpo 2005).
[4] For instance, scholars began to question and criticize the dependency framework, particularly its seeming oversimplification— the absence of autonomy of the Philippine government and the overwhelming American influence over it.

[6] See discussion on the dependency framework.