This is an Author's Original Manuscript of an article published by College of Public Affairs and Development, University of the Philippines Los Banos in “ Journal of Public Affairs and Development (JPAD)” on 2015.
Assessing
the Legislative Politics in the Making of
the Foreign Bank Liberalization Act[1]
Bing
Baltazar C. Brillo[2]
Abstract
The
study is about the dynamics among the actors in the making of the Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act or Republic Act 7721. The central issue in the legislation
was whether to have a restricted or extensive liberalization of the banking
sector. The policy divide was between the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign
banks’ bloc, which was advocating for a single-mode of entry for foreign banks,
and the House-FCCP-the rural-development banks-the academic-business-consumer
groups’ bloc, which was endorsing a multiple-mode of entry for foreign banks.
The Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc prevailed since their bloc
benefited from three intertwined factors in the legislation process. First, the
inevitability of the liberalization of the banking sector left the domestic
commercial banks with no recourse but to take an all-out effort to push for a limited
liberalization law. Second, the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc was
aided by the collective action dilemma among the actors. And third, the internal
dynamics among the members of the Senate and the House made it very difficult
for the former and tolerable for the latter to compromise.
Keywords
Policy
Making, Legislative Politics, Pluralism
Republic
Act 7721 and Foreign Bank Liberalization Law
Introduction
Under the era of economic nationalism, the General
Banking Act of 1948 restructured the landscape of the banking industry. The law
made the banking system exclusively for Filipinos and placed a moratorium on
the entry of new foreign banks in the country. The rationale was by limiting
competition from foreign banks, the domestic banks would get the needed
protection and the opportunity to expand. Through the decades, this protective
condition made the banking industry very profitable. The financial success of
domestic banks, however, had detrimental effects; as the restricted competition
led to an oligopoly in the banking sector. This condition was manifested in undue
concentration of bank deposits among few large domestic banks, in the huge gap
between savings and borrowings interest rate, and in the poor performance of
the local banking sector relative to ASEAN neighbors. With these, calls were
made for the lifting of the moratorium and opening of the banking sector to
foreign competition. Since the move was expected to bring efficiency,
innovations and better services in the banking industry, the Ramos
administration took the cudgel in legislating the foreign bank liberalization
law.
This study is about the diversity among political
actors in the making of the Foreign Bank Liberalization Act (FBLA) or Republic
Act (RA) 7721. The emphasis was on the actors’ engagement in the formal
legislation process, specifically, on the policy divide between having a
restrictive or extensive bank liberalization law. In answering why the FBLA
took a particular shape, the research made a detailed assessment of the
interaction among the legislative actors and stakeholders. The paper proceeds
as follows: first, it explains the pluralist perspective in policy making
analysis; second, it discusses the move towards a foreign bank liberalization policy;
third, it illustrates the foreign bank liberalization’s policy divide; fourth,
it elucidates the legislative dynamics among the policy actors; and lastly, it
presents the concluding remarks.
Pluralist
Perspective in Policy Making Analysis
There are two existing studies on the legislation of
banking policy in the Philippines— Paul Hutchcroft’s Booty Capitalism: the Politics of Banking in the Philippines in
1998; and Antonio Pedro and Eric Batalla’s The
Politics of Financial Liberalization in 2002.[3]
The first represents the weak state-elitist tradition, the dominant perspective
in interpreting Philippine policy making (see Quirino 1974; McCoy 1988; De Dios
1990; Rivera 1991; Montes 1992; Almonte 1993; McCoy 1993; Hutchcroft 1993;
Caoili 1993; Rivera 1994; Gutierrez 1994; Doronila 1994; Rocamora 1998; Almonte 2007; Magno 2009), and the
second represents the pluralist tradition, the minority perspective.
Considered as a pioneering work in the politics of
banking policy, Hutchcroft, using the concept of booty capitalism, contended
that the oligarchs have captured the Philippine state and that this condition
has allowed them to skew the banking policies to their favor. This oligarchic
domination has resulted in the unpredictability and inconsistency of banking
policies, and in the systematic plunder of the banking sector, via abuse of its
loan portfolios and cartel practices. On the whole, Hutchroft’s work suggested cohesiveness
or homogeneity among the political actors controlling the government’s legislative
mechanism. Pedro and Batalla’s work took off from Hutchcroft’s work by
critiquing the later. Focusing on the business-government relationship, Pedro
and Batalla argued that the fragmentation among business elites prevented the
state’s capture and allowed the government the leeway to pass the financial
liberalization policy.[4]
This analysis hinted that, instead of cohesiveness, there was increasing
pluralism among the political actors in contemporary Philippine polity.
Taking cue from the literature, the study adopted
the pluralist perspective in exploring the dynamics in Philippine policy
making. The pluralist perspective views the legislative process as an arena
among competing interests, and the policy as a decision which reflects the equilibrium
among the interacting actors (see Truman 1951; Bentley 1967; Dahl 1961, 1967
and 1971; Lindblom 1977). This perspective assumes that actors are autonomous
and takes diversified position vis-à-vis their interest in the policy making
equation (Self 1985; Smith 1990; Howlett and Ramesh 1995). Following this assumption,
the actors in the study were deemed autonomous collective actors who take
actions to influence the legislative process and outcome.
In the policy making of the FBLA, the principal
collective actors are the legislature, the bureaucracy and the interest groups.
The legislature corresponds to the two chambers of the Philippine Congress— the
Senate and the House of Representatives. The bureaucracy corresponds to the main
government agency that actively took part in the legislative deliberations— the
Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP). And the interest groups refer to the gamut
of non-governmental actors that vigorously participated in the legislation
process— (1) the Bankers Association of the Philippines (BAP) which represents
the domestic commercial banks’ interest; (2) the four resident foreign banks—
Bank of America (BA), Citibank, Hong Kong Shanghai Bank (HKSB), and Standard
Chartered Bank (SCB) which refers the existing foreign banks in the country
prior to the FBLA; (3) Rural Bankers Association of the Philippines (RBAP) and
Development Bank of the Philippines (DBP) which represents the rural-development
banks’ interest; (3) the Foreign Chambers of Commerce in the Philippines (FCCP) [5]
which represents the foreign banks’ interest; and (4) the academic-business-consumer
groups[6]
which converge via a liberalization policy lobby group.
The actors’ engagement in policy making was
delineated via the two diverging positions. On one hand, the Senate, the BSP,
the resident foreign banks, and the BAP favoring the banking sector’s restricted
opening to foreign banks. On the other hand, the House of Representatives, rural-development
banks, the academic-business-consumer groups, and the FCCP supporting the banking
sector’s extensive opening to foreign banks. This issue would be the central
point in the legislation of the FBLA.
Moving
towards a Foreign Bank Liberalization Policy
In the era when economic nationalism
reigned over the banking sector, the Philippine legislature enacted the General
Banking Act or RA 337 in 1948 (Batalla 2002; Pedro 2002).The law, as it delineated
the authority of the Monetary Board, became the principal regulatory statute of
the Philippine banking sector. Prior to the law there were 28 domestic-owned
banks and four foreign banks operating in the Philippines— BA since 1947,
Citibank since 1902, HKSB since 1867, and SCB since 1872. The General Banking
Act strategically altered the banking industry since it limited the number of
banks and encouraged them to increase their size. The rationale behind the
policy was that fewer but bigger banks would promote soundness and stability in
the banking sector. The regulatory statute essentially made the banking system exclusive
for Filipinos by restricting the branching of existing foreign banks and entry
of new foreign banks (Milo 2001). In effect, the law “fossilized” the existing
foreign banks to whatever branches they had and placed a moratorium on the
entry of other foreign banks in the country. By limiting competition from
foreign banks, the thinking was that domestic banks would get the needed protection,
the opportunity to expand, and the assurance that the banking sector would be
firmly in the hands of Filipino bankers.
With the restriction on the entry and branching of
foreign banks continuing throughout the 1970s and 1980s, the local banking
sector through the years became one of the most profitable industries in the
Philippines (Milo 2001). The financial success of domestic banks, however, had a
downside. The restricted competition in the banking sector was seen as
detrimental to the economy, the public, and the long term viability of the banking
industry. For instance, one prominent issue against the prevailing banking
system was the undue concentration of bank deposits among few large domestic
banks. The two studies conducted by the Center for Research and Communication
(CRC)[7]
in 1991 and the Philippine National Bank (PNB) in 1992 showed that seven banks
account for 63 and 62.2 percent, respectively, of the total deposits and 66.9 and
63.3 percent, respectively, of the total savings deposits (Congress of the
Philippines-House Committee Hearings October 19, 1992). This oligopolistic
condition was often equated to the existence of a banking cartel. Moreover,
this situation was exacerbated when the huge profits of domestic banks was
superimposed on the bank spread[8]
(i.e. the gap between deposits and lending rates). As it was, there existed a
wide gap between the low interest rate on savings (around 6 percent) and the high
interest rate on borrowings (around 24 percent) which translated to a heavy
burden on borrowers and an enormous windfall for domestic commercial banks.
Another was the issue of the local banking industry being
at the bottom in terms of the number of foreign banks relative to ASEAN
neighbors. The Philippines with four foreign banks (compared to 14 in Thailand,
16 in Malaysia, 11 in Indonesia, and 36 in Singapore) had the smallest number
of foreign commercial banks. In addition, as cited by CRC, among the ASEAN
countries (aside from Thailand)[9]
the Philippines was the only banking market that did not allow the entry of
foreign banks (Congress of the Philippines-House Committee Hearings October 19,
1992).[10] The closed-protective nature of the domestic banking
industry denied competition from foreign banks. With this condition, the
consensus in government was to open the banking sector to foreign banks to
foster more competition which eventually was expected to redound to more efficiency,
innovations and better services.
The call for the liberalization of the banking
industry began in the early 1980s when the Government of Corazon Aquino undertook
the reformulation of economic policies toward greater liberalization. The ensuing
political problems that threatened the survival of the administration, however,
have stalled most of these liberalization reforms (Pedro 2002). In the 1990s,
the liberalization program gradually permeated the banking sector; starting with
relaxation of restrictions on the entry and branching of domestic banks and the
call for the lifting of moratorium on the entry and operations of foreign banks
(Milo 2001). In 1991 a formal action was taken by Representative Margarito
Teves when he filed House Bill 35068 in the Eighth Congress calling for the amendment
of the General Banking Act of 1948 to liberalize the entry and scope of
operations of foreign banks in the country. The bill was approved in the House
of Representatives, but no corresponding action was made in the Senate (Pedro
2002). After the May 1992 elections, the newly installed administration of
President Fidel Ramos made it a priority to accelerate the phase of the
liberalization of the economy. With the commitment of the Ramos administration,
Representative Teves re-filed the same bill (now House Bill 263) in the Ninth
Congress. Months later, the Senate followed suit. Several bills were filed with
the aim of allowing the entry of foreign banks, namely: Senate Bill 839 (Senator
Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo), Senate Bill 1474 (Senators Edgardo Angara, Raul Roco,
Blas Ople and Neptali Gonzales), and Senate Bill 1653 (Senator Leticia
Ramos-Shahani). [11]
Summary
of the Lawmaking Proceedings. In the House of Representatives, House
Bill 263 was heard through a joint meeting between the Committee on Banks and
Financial Intermediaries, chaired by Representative Jose Carlos Lacson, and the
Committee on Economic Affairs, chaired by Representative Felicito Payumo. The
joint hearing came out with Committee Report no. 112 on House Bill 8226 (in
substitution to House Bill 263). In the Senate, on the other hand, Senate Bills
839, 1474 and 1653 were heard by the Committee on Banks, Financial Institution
and Currencies, chaired by Senator Raul Roco. The hearing resulted in Committee
Report no. 316 on Senate Bill 1606 (consolidated version of the bills 839, 1474
and 1653). On 2 February 1994 President Ramos certified the bill as priority
legislation. The House approved the bill on the Second Reading on 17 May 1993
and Third Reading on 10 June 1993 (120 affirmative votes, 2 against, and 0
abstentation); while the Senate approved the Second and Third Reading on 24
March 1994 (14 affirmative votes, 2 against and 2 abstentations). The House and
Senate version of the bill were reconciled and approved by the Bicameral
Conference Committee (Bicam), and ratified by both chambers on 17 May 1994.The
foreign bank liberalization law was formally signed by the President on 18 May
1994, and became RA 7721.
Foreign Bank Liberalization’s
Policy Divide
The move to legislate the foreign bank
liberalization law was anchored on three objectives: first, to generate greater
competition in the banking industry so as to enhance efficiency and banking
services; second, to further integrate the Philippine economy to the global
economy; and third, to encourage dispersal of ownership in the banking industry
in keeping with the policy of breaking up cartels and monopolies (Congress of
the Philippines-Senate Session Proceedings January 24, 1994). The foreign bank
liberalization law was also seen as supplementary and complimentary to then
recently enacted Foreign Investment Act (RA 7042) since the law was conceived
to further induce and facilitate the inflow of foreign investments.
The main
issue in the legislation was extent of the liberalization, which is whether to
have a restricted or extensive opening of the banking sector to foreign banks.
Empirically, the concern boiled down to the modes of entry for foreign banks in
the banking sector. The entry of foreign banks can
take three forms— branching, subsidiary, or acquisition. In branching, the
foreign bank simply expands its scope of operation by putting up a branch that
is an extension unit in the Philippines. In subsidiary, the foreign bank enters
by establishing a wholly or majority locally incorporated bank. And in
acquisition, the foreign bank’s entry is through outright purchase of the
equity of an existing domestic bank or joint venture arrangement, preferably,
distressed or banks that need to be rehabilitated.
The mode of entry issue polarized the policy actors
into two positions: the Senate’s position which is for a
limited opening of the banking sector, and the House’s position which is for an
extensive opening of the banking sector. In particular, the Senate version restricts
to a single mode of entry where a foreign bank once chosen a particular mode
cannot anymore avail of the other modes, while the House version allows for
multiple mode of entry where a foreign bank can avail of one or all three modes
of entering and operating in the country. Moreover, the Senate-House divide was
also manifested in other subsidiary issues. For instance, on the number of
branches a foreign bank can establish, the Senate version limits to a total of
ten branches only, while the House version has no limits. On the issue of
equity ownership, the Senate version restricts the equity ceiling to only 60
percent, whereas the House version allows up to 70 percent equity for foreign
banks. And on the time frame of the entry of foreign banks, the Senate version limits
the period of entry of foreign banks to five years, while the House version
provides no limitation.
The Senate’s position was strongly supported by the
BSP, the BAP and the resident foreign banks. The BAP and the resident foreign
banks’ behavior was consistent with protecting their interests, as allowing
more foreign banks coming would mean more competition for them which could translate to less market share and profit. In
other words, the domestic commercial banks and the four existing foreign banks
would like to lessen the repercussion of the liberalization policy and maintain
the advantages that they enjoyed in the past via restrictive competition. With
this intention, the BAP and the resident foreign banks’ ardently lobbied the
Senate for a single mode of entry for foreign banks. The BAP and the resident
foreign banks’ influence was evident when Senator Gonzales admitted that the
single mode entry proposal came at their behest (Congress of the Philippines-
Bicameral Conference Committee April 21, 1994).
The BSP’s support for the Senate’s version was in
line with the government agency’s commitment in protecting the domestic
commercial banks. This relationship between the BSP and the domestic commercial
banks was underpinned by the strong bond between the BSP leadership and the
BAP, as the past and present heads of the former usually come from the latter. Accordingly,
the BSP, in the committee hearings, argued that allowing multiple entries,
specifically, the acquisition and subsidiary mode, would prejudice domestic
commercial banks, and that by concentrating on just one mode the legislation
would be hastened. Here, the BSP cited that allowing the two other modes would
violate provisions in the General Banking Act (specifically, Section 12-A, 12-B
and 12-D), and hence, would complicate and delay the legislative proceedings.
The BSP’s position was formally stated by Feliciano Miranda: “the Monetary
Board has adopted the position that amendments to existing provisions of RA No.
337, as amended, be limited to provisions governing the entry of foreign banks
only thru the establishment of branches in the Philippines” (Congress of the
Philippines-House Committee Hearings October 19, 1992: 23).
Moreover, the Senate’s position in favor for a
restricted liberalization law was buoyed by the prevailing nationalist
sentiment among its members that the local banks would need protection from the
competition that would come from the influx of foreign banks (Congress of the
Philippines-House Conference Committee Report May 16, 1994). This sentiment was
made clear by Senator Gonzales in the Bicameral Conference Committee, when he
admonished the body that its primary consideration was the protection of
domestic banks (Congress of the Philippines- Bicameral Conference Committee
April 21, 1994).
The House’s position, on the other hand, was strongly
supported by the FCCP, the rural-development banks, and the
academic-business-consumer groups. The FCCP’s support to a more encompassing
opening of the banking sector was a given since its members— the American,
Canadian, Australian-New Zealand, Japanese, and European Chamber of Commerce of
the Philippines— would directly benefit from the liberalization law. Foreign
banks would not only gain access to the Philippine market but could avail of
multiple-entry options.
The rural-development banks’ support for the House
bill was anchored on the perception that the liberalization law has no serious
deleterious effect on them. For instance, DBP, representing development banks, believed
that their operations would be unaffected, as multilateral institutions (e.g.
WB, IMF and ADB)[12]
prefer to do business, such as providing development financial assistance,
through the government’s development bank, with or without the entry of foreign
banks. While RBAP, representing rural banks, believed that foreign banks have a
different customer base, and would not establish branches in rural areas; hence,
foreign banks would not directly compete with the rural banks for market share.
Moreover, RBAP sensed that with the entry of more foreign banks, the rural
banks would benefit, as they anticipate potential business partners and expects
a boost in their remittance business.
The academic-business-consumer groups’ support for
the House’s version was grounded on the consensus that the extensive
liberalization of the banking sector would redound to their benefit and to the
country as a whole. For instance, PCCI, representing the business industry, and
NEPA, representing the consumers, stated publicly that the expected increase in
competition in the banking sector brought about by the entry of foreign banks,
overall, would be better for the entire business sector and the consumers. The
ideological rationalization on this was supplied by the academic groups, in
particular, PIDS and CRC. For instance, PIDS’ Dr. Mario Lamberte (1993), arguing
for the multiple modes of entry for foreign banks, contended that partial
deregulation will have less meaningful effect since the aim is to create a
contestable financial market where the threat of potential entry must be
credible and sufficient to force incumbents to behave like a competitor. He
further explained that there is no need to restrict the opening of the banking
sector, as the market will ultimately determine the optimal number of foreign
banks in the country. While CRC elucidated on the expected benefits of full
liberalization, such as market de-concentration, lower loan rates and efficient
performance of the banking market, and as evidence, cited the success
experienced by other ASEAN countries when they implemented extensive
liberalization in their banking sector.
Moreover, the House of Representatives’ position in
favor for an extensive liberalization law was buoyed by the prevailing
sentiment among its members that the country urgently needs to send a strong
signal to the international community in order to compensate for its lateness
in liberalizing the banking sector (Congress of the Philippines-House
Conference Committee Report May 16, 1994). This sentiment corresponds with the
Ramos administration’s desire to accelerate economic growth and help the
Philippines to catch up with its neighboring ASEAN countries.
The Legislative
Dynamics among the Policy Actors
The policy divide between the
Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc (who is advocating for a restricted
foreign bank liberalization law), and the House-FCCP-the rural-development
banks-the academic-business-consumer groups’ bloc (who is endorsing an
extensive liberalization policy) was settled when the legislature came up with
a law that partially liberalized the entry and operations of foreign banks. Thus,
the Foreign Bank Liberalization Act or RA 7721 reflected the position of the
Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc. The restrictiveness of the FBLA
was shown in the following sections of the law.
Sec. 2. Modes of Entry. — The Monetary Board may authorize
foreign banks to operate in the Philippine banking system through any of the
following modes of entry: (i) by acquiring, purchasing or owning up to sixty
percent (60%) of the voting stock of an existing bank; (ii) by investing in up
to sixty percent (60%) of the voting stock of a new banking subsidiary
incorporated under the laws of the Philippines; or (iii) by establishing
branches with full banking authority: Provided, That a foreign bank may
avail itself of only one (1) mode of entry: Provided, further, That a
foreign bank or a Philippine corporation may own up to a sixty percent (60%) of
the voting stock of only one (1) domestic bank or new banking subsidiary.
Sec. 4, (ii) For Foreign Bank Branches. — The
foreign bank may open three (3) additional branches in locations designated
by the Monetary Board by inwardly remitting and converting into Philippine
currency as permanently assigned capital, the U.S. dollar equivalent of
Thirty-five million pesos (P35,000,000.00) per additional branch at the exchange
rate on the date of the effectivity of this Act, as ascertained by the Monetary
Board. The total number of branches for each new foreign bank entrant shall
not exceed six (6).
Sec. 6. Entrants under Section 2(iii). — Foreign
banks shall be allowed entry under Section 2 (iii) within five (5) years
from the effectivity of this Act. During this period, six (6) new foreign
banks shall be allowed entry under Section 2(iii) upon the approval of the
Monetary Board.[13]
Sec. 10. Transitory Provisions. — Foreign banks
operating through branches in the Philippines upon the effectivity of this Act,
shall be eligible for the privilege of establishing up to six (6) additional
branches under the same terms and conditions required by Section 4 (ii)
hereof. [14] [15]
The policy making process and outcome was shaped by
three intertwined factors present in the legislation. The first factor is that
the policy actors were working on the premised that economic liberalization is
the government’s framework for economic development since post-EDSA (see Brillo
2010a; Brillo 2010b). The Ramos administration did not only continue the
liberalization policy of its predecessor but considerably accelerated the liberalization
of the economy. The Ramos administration showed its unwavering commitment
towards liberalization when the government spearheaded the enactment of the
Foreign Investment Act, reorganized the Central Bank, and dismantled the monopoly
in the telecommunications industry (Pedro 2002). In the legislation of the
FBLA, the Ramos administration’s resolute commitment to liberalization has made
the opening of the banking sector to foreign banks inevitable to both the
Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc and the House-FCCP-the
rural-development banks-the academic-business-consumer groups’ bloc. For the directly
affected sector, specifically the BAP and the resident foreign banks, the
certainty of the foreign bank liberalization law was already a concession to
the government. Henceforth, the BAP and the resident foreign banks became so determined
to make an all-out push for the only logical remedy available to them— influence
the law’s formulation to ensure that some level of protection is afforded to
them.
The second factor is that the policy making equation
among the actors suffered from collective action dilemma. The dilemma happens
when the costs are immediately felt and concentrated on a small group while the
benefits have long-term impact and spread to a much larger group. This scenario
creates strong incentives for the former and disincentives for the latter to
mobilize for collective action (see Olsen 1965). The situation intensifies when
the small group is highly organized, well funded, and politically influential,
compared to the larger group (Reich 2002). In the case of the FBLA, the collective
action dilemma benefited the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc
against the House-FCCP-the rural-development banks-the academic-business-consumer
groups’ bloc. (1) As to the costs, the BAP and the resident foreign banks were expected
to bear the brunt of the liberalization policy. Being the sectors directly
threatened, the BAP and the resident foreign banks have strong incentive to
intervene and heavily influence the policy outcome. Compared to the
rural-development banks and the FCCP- academic-business-consumer groups, the
former would not be significantly affected while the latter perceived gains in
the long term; hence, they have less incentive to intensify the move to
influence the policy outcome. (2) As to the strength of the contending groups,
the BAP and the resident foreign banks have the advantage since their groups,
overall, were more organized, have the financial muscle and the political
connections. Relative to the rural-development banks and the FCCP- academic-business-consumer
groups, the former was minuscule (in size, capital and market) compared to the
domestic commercial banks, and the latter, in general, was broad-based (as to
the academic-business-consumer groups) and an external actor (as to the FCCP).
In consequence, the rural-development banks, the FCCP and academic-business-consumer
groups took a more moderate involvement in the legislation process compared to
the aggressive stance put up by the BAP throughout the proceedings. Moreover,
the BAP and the resident foreign banks’ cause was boosted by the support of
their patron agency, the BSP. The BSP’s involvement was significant since its opinion
had more weight to the lawmakers being the principal government agency for the
banking sector.
The third factor is that the internal politics that
exist in the Senate and the House of Representatives. The Senate, as a
legislative body, has long been regarded for its members’ independence in
decision making (Caoili 2006; Brillo 2013). The Senators usually exhibits more
autonomy (in relation to their leadership’s position or their political party’s
stand) in voting over a bill. In the legislation of the FBLA, the autonomy of
the Senators was visible from the opposition’s unwavering quest to provide protection
to domestic commercial banks amid the anticipated influx of foreign banks.[16]
In effect, the Senate’s committee chair Senator Raul Roco had to make
considerable concessions, via restrictive measures in the policy, to appease the
opposition not to block the bill’s passage and at the same time, ensure the
necessary number of votes to approve it. Thus, with its commitments to the
opposition, the Senate became very firm in its position, particularly during
the Bicameral Conference Committee. On the other hand, the House of
Representatives has long been regarded for its members’ submissive behavior in
decision-making (Gutierrez 1994; Coronel et al. 2004). The Congressmen, in
general, are more obedient to their leadership’s position (regardless of party
affiliations) in voting over a bill. In the legislation of the FBLA, the
submissiveness of the Congressmen was shown when chamber readily acceded to the
request by its leadership to swiftly approve the extensively liberalized
version of the bill with no modifications. Since the House of Representatives’
position was largely determined by its leadership, the chambers policy stand
was more flexible in the sense that it did not have commitments to the
opposition to satisfy and that its members tend to accept the compromises entered
into by their leaders, particularly during the Bicameral Conference Committee. Thus,
the unyieldingness of the opposition in the Senate and the acquiescence of
members of the House Representative to their leadership made it difficult for
the former and tolerable for the latter to enter to a compromise in the
Bicameral Conference Committee.
Concluding
Remarks
In the move to legislate the foreign bank
liberalization law, the central issue was whether to have a restricted or
extensive liberalization of the banking sector. The issue divided the policy
actors into the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc, which was
advocating for a single-mode of entry for foreign banks, and the House-FCCP-the
rural-development banks-the academic-business-consumer groups’ bloc, which was
endorsing a multiple-mode of entry for foreign banks. The Senate’s position was
underpinned by the sentiment that it must give protection to the domestic commercial
banks. The BSP supported the Senate position since it was also committed to
promoting the interest of the domestic banks; while the BAP-the resident
foreign banks saw the urgent need to defend their advantage. On the other hand,
the House’s position was underscored by the sentiment that all-encompassing
liberalization is essential to jumpstarting economic growth. The FCCP supported
the House position since it anticipated gaining a foothold on the local banking
market; while the rural-development banks saw no serious adverse effect and the
academic-business-consumer groups believed that extensive liberalization is
better for everyone.
The Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc
prevailed over the policy divide via a law that partially liberalized the entry
and operations of foreign banks. The legislative politics was characterized by
three intertwined factors. First, the inevitability of the liberalization of
the banking sector left the directly affected sector— the domestic commercial banks—
with no alternative but to make an all out push for a restrictive liberalization
law. Second, the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident foreign banks’ bloc benefited from the
collective action dilemma which strengthened their resolve and position. And
third, the prevailing characteristic among the members of the Senate and the House
made it very difficult for the former and tolerable for the latter to
compromise. Summing up, these factors generated
a policy making dynamics that reinforced the position of the Senate-BSP-BAP-resident
foreign banks’ bloc and weakened the position of the House-FCCP-the
rural-development banks-the academic-business-consumer groups’ bloc, hence,
sealing a more restrictive FBLA.
References
Almonte,
Jose. 1993.
The Politics of Development in the
Philippines. Kasarinlan: Philippine
Journal of Third World Studies, 9(2) 107-116.
Almonte,
Jose. 2007. To Put Our House in Order: We
Must Level the Playing Field. Manila: Foundation for Economic Freedom, Inc.
Batalla,
Eric. 2002. The Politics of Financial Liberalization. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization:
Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco
Center/DLSU.
Bentley,
Arthur. 1967. The Process of Government.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Brillo,
Bing Baltazar. 2010a. The Nationalization and Liberalization of the Retail
Trade Industry in the Philippines.
Danyag: Journal of Humanities and Social Sciences, 15(1) 55-67.
Brillo,
Bing Baltazar. 2010b. The Politics of the Anti-Dumping Law of the Philippines. UP Los Banos Journal, 8(1) 17-29.
Brillo,
Bing Baltazar. 2013. Bureaucracy-Legislature
Dynamics under the Intervention of a Multilateral Institution: the Policy
Making of the AMLA. Ph.D. dissertation,
De La Salle University.
Caoili,
Olivia. 1993. The Philippine Congress: Executive- Legislative Relations and
the Restoration of Democracy. Quezon
City: UP-CIDS and UP Press.
Caoili, Olivia.
2006. The Restored Philippine Congress. In Noel Morada and Teresa Tadem (eds.),
Philippine Politics and Governance.
Quezon City: University of the Philippines Diliman.
Congress
of the Philippines. 1992. House Committee
Hearings (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries joint with
Economic Affairs, October 19).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1992. House Committee
Hearings. (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries joint with
Economic Affairs, October 22).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1993. House Committee
Hearings (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries joint with
Economic Affairs, February 3).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1993. House Committee
Hearings. (Committee on Banks and Financial Intermediaries joint with
Economic Affairs, February 9).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1993. Senate Committee
Hearings. (Committee on Banks, Financial Institutions and Currencies,
November 9).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1993. House Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank Liberalization Act (March 30).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1993. House Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 31).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Bicameral
Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill 8226 (April 21).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Bicameral
Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill 8226 (April 26).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Bicameral
Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill 8226 (May 4).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. House
Consideration of the Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill
8226 (May 16).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. House
Consideration of the Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill
8226 (May 17).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate
Committee Hearings. (Committee on Banks, Financial Institutions and
Currencies, January 6).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate
Committee Hearings. (Committee on Banks, Financial Institutions and
Currencies, January 12).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate
Consideration of the Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill
8226 (May 16).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate
Consideration of the Conference Committee on Senate Bill 1606 and House Bill
8226 (May 17).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank Liberalization Act (January 24).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (January 31).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 7).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 10).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 21).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 22).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 23).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 24).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (February 28).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 3).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank Liberalization
Act (March 9).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 16).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 21).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 23).
Congress
of the Philippines. 1994. Senate Session
Proceedings on Foreign Bank
Liberalization Act (March 24).
Coronel, Shiela, Yvonne Chua, Luz Rimban and Boomba Cruz. 2004. The Rulemakers: How the
Wealth and Well-Born Dominate Congress. Quezon City: PCIJ.
Dahl,
Robert. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy in
an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Dahl,
Robert. 1967. Pluralist Democracy in the
United States. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Dahl,
Robert. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation
and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
De Dios, Emmanuel. 1990. A Political Economy of Philippine Policy-Making.
In John W. Langford and K. Lorne Brownsey (eds.), Economic
Policy-Making in the Asia-Pacific Region. Halifax, Nova Scotia: Institute for Research on Public Policy.
Doronila,
Amando. 1994.
Reflections on a Weak State and
Dilemma of Decentralization
Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 10(1) 48-54.
Gutierrez,
Eric. 1994. The Ties that Bind: A Guide
to Family, Business and Other Interests in the Ninth House of Representatives.
Pasig: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism.
Hapitan,
Rene. 2001. From the Local Banks’ Perspective: Feeling the Liberalization
Effects. Development Research News,
19(5), 1-3.
Howlett,
Michael and M Ramesh. 1995. Studying
Public Policy: Policy Cycles and Policy Subsystems. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Hutchcroft, Paul.
1993. Selective Squander: The Politics of Preferential Credit Allocation in the
Philippines. In Stephan Haggard, Chung H. Lee, and Sylvia Maxfield (eds.), The
Politics of Finance in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press.
Hutchroft,
Paul. 1998. Booty Capitalism: The
Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Ithaca: Cornel University Press.
Lamberte, Mario.
1993. Assessment of the Financial Market Reforms in the Philippines, 1980-1992.
Philippine Institute for Development Studies:
Journal of Philippine Development, Second Semester (1993 Volume 10, No. 2) 231-259.
Lindblom,
Charles. 1977. Politics and Markets.
New York: Basic Books.
Magno,
Alexander. 2009. Weak State. First
Person, The Philippine Star, October 8, 1. http://www.philstar.com/Article.aspx?articleid=512148
McCoy,
Alfred. 1988. Quezon’s Commonwealth: The Emergence of Philippine
Authoritarianism. In Ruby Paredes
(ed.), Philippine Colonial Democracy.
New Haven: Yale Center for International and Area Studies.
McCoy,
Alfred. 1993. An Anarchy of Families:
State and Family in the Philippines. Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press.
Milo,
Melanie. 2001. Deregulation of Bank Entry and Branching: Impact on Competition.
Philippine Institute for Development
Studies: Policy Notes, December (2001-16) 1-6.
Montes, Manuel. 1992. The Politics of
Liberalization: The Aquino Government’s 1990 Tariff Reform Initiative. In David
Timberman (ed.), The Politics of Economic
Reform in Southeast Asia. Makati: Asian Institute of Management.
Olsen,
Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective
Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Pedro,
Antonio. 2002. Legislating Banking Liberalization in the Philippines:
Business-Government Relations in Policy Reform. In Eric Batalla (ed.), The Politics of Financial Liberalization:
Foreign Banking in Japan and the Philippines. Manila: Yuchengco
Center/DLSU.
Quirino,
Carlos. 1974. History of the Philippine
Sugar Industry. Manila: Kalayaan Publishing.
Reich,
Michael. 2002. The Politics of Reforming
Health Policies. http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/ pubmed/12731117
Rivera,
Temario. 1991. Class, the State and
Foreign Capital: The Politics of Philippine Industrialization, 1950-1986.
Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin.
Rivera,
Temario. 1994. The State and Industrial Transformation: Comparative and Local
Insights. Kasarinlan: Philippine Journal of Third World Studies, 10(1) 55-80.
Rocamora,
Joel. 1998. Philippine Political Parties:
Continuity and Change. Quezon City: Institute for Popular Democracy.
Self,
Peter. 1985. Political Theories of Modern
Government: Its Role and Reform. London: Allen and Unwin.
Smith,
Martin. 1990. Pluralism, Reformed Pluralism and Neopluralism: The Role of
Pressure Groups in Policy-Making. Political
Studies, 38( ) 303-304.
Tiglao, Rigoberto. 1992. The Dilemmas of Economic
Policymaking in a “People Power” State. In David Timberman (ed.), The Politics of Economic Reform in Southeast
Asia. Makati: Asian Institute of Management.
Truman,
David. 1951. The Governmental Process.
New York: Knoft.
[1] The author wishes to thank the anonymous reviewers, but assumes full
responsibility for the article.
[2] The author has Ph.D. in Development Studies and is Assistant
Professor at the Department of Social Sciences, University of the Philippines
Los Baños.
[3] Batalla is the book’s editor and Pedro’s article is entitled
Legislating Banking Liberation in the Philippines: Business-Government
Relations in Policy Reform.
[4] For earlier work on the fragmentation in Philippine politics see
Tiglao 1992.
[5] American Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines (ACC), Canadian
Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines (CCC), Australian-New Zealand Chamber of
Commerce of the Philippines (A/NZC), Japanese Chamber of Commerce and Industry
of the Philippines (JCCI), and the European Chamber of Commerce of the
Philippines (ECC).
[6] The Center for
Research and Communication (CRC), the Philippine Institute for Development
Studies (PIDS), Philippine Exporters Confederation (PhilExport), National
Economic Protectionism Association (NEPA), and the Philippine Chamber of
Commerce and Industry (PCCI).
[7] CRC is a private
think-tank that conducts economic and social research. It is now the University
of Asia and the Pacific.
[8] In general, bank spread refers to the difference
between the interest
rate a bank charges a borrower
and the interest rate a bank pays a depositor (http://www.special-loans.com/dictionary)
[9] Although Thailand does not allow the entry of foreign banks, it has
more foreign banks operating compared to the Philippines.
[10]In 1993, the existing four foreign banks have a total of nine
branches while the 32 domestic banks have an aggregate total of 2360 branches.
[11] This paragraph relied heavily from Pedro 2002.
[12] World Bank, International Monetary Fund and Asian Development Bank.
[13] An additional four (4) foreign
banks may be allowed entry on recommendation of the Monetary Board, subject to
compliance with Sections 2, 3, 4, and 5 of this Act, upon approval of the
President as the national interest may require.
[14] Underscoring was made for emphasis.
[15] Overall, only 10 foreign banks were allowed entry to operate by the
FBLA (Hapitan 2001).
[16] Notably Senators Arturo
Tolentino, Ernesto Maceda, Anna Dominique Coseteng, and Wigberto Tanada
[1] The author wishes to thank the anonymous reviewers, but assumes full
responsibility for the article.
[2] The author has Ph.D. in Development Studies and is Assistant
Professor at the Department of Social Sciences, University of the Philippines
Los Baños.
[3] Batalla is the book’s editor and Pedro’s article is entitled
Legislating Banking Liberation in the Philippines: Business-Government
Relations in Policy Reform.
[4] For earlier work on the fragmentation in Philippine politics see
Tiglao 1992.
[5] American Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines (ACC), Canadian
Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines (CCC), Australian-New Zealand Chamber of
Commerce of the Philippines (A/NZC), Japanese Chamber of Commerce and Industry
of the Philippines (JCCI), and the European Chamber of Commerce of the
Philippines (ECC).
[6] The Center for
Research and Communication (CRC), the Philippine Institute for Development
Studies (PIDS), Philippine Exporters Confederation (PhilExport), National
Economic Protectionism Association (NEPA), and the Philippine Chamber of
Commerce and Industry (PCCI).
[7] CRC is a private
think-tank that conducts economic and social research. It is now the University
of Asia and the Pacific.
[8] In general, bank spread refers to the difference
between the interest
rate a bank charges a borrower
and the interest rate a bank pays a depositor (http://www.special-loans.com/dictionary)
[9] Although Thailand does not allow the entry of foreign banks, it has
more foreign banks operating compared to the Philippines.
[10]In 1993, the existing four foreign banks have a total of nine
branches while the 32 domestic banks have an aggregate total of 2360 branches.
[11] This paragraph relied heavily from Pedro 2002.
[12] World Bank, International Monetary Fund and Asian Development Bank.
[13] An additional four (4) foreign
banks may be allowed entry on recommendation of the Monetary Board, subject to
compliance with Sections 2, 3, 4, and 5 of this Act, upon approval of the
President as the national interest may require.
[14] Underscoring was made for emphasis.
[15] Overall, only 10 foreign banks were allowed entry to operate by the
FBLA (Hapitan 2001).
[16] Notably Senators Arturo
Tolentino, Ernesto Maceda, Anna Dominique Coseteng, and Wigberto Tanada
No comments:
Post a Comment